Jump to content
Main menu
Main menu
move to sidebar
hide
Navigation
Main page
Recent changes
Random page
Help about MediaWiki
Special pages
Niidae Wiki
Search
Search
Appearance
Create account
Log in
Personal tools
Create account
Log in
Pages for logged out editors
learn more
Contributions
Talk
Editing
Feminist economics
Page
Discussion
English
Read
Edit
View history
Tools
Tools
move to sidebar
hide
Actions
Read
Edit
View history
General
What links here
Related changes
Page information
Appearance
move to sidebar
hide
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
{{short description|Gender-aware branch of economics}} {{About|the discipline|the journal|Feminist Economics (journal){{!}}''Feminist Economics'' (journal)}} {{Good article}} [[File:Ms. magazine Cover - Spring 1972.jpg|thumbnail|The first issue of ''[[Ms. magazine]]'' examined feminist economics in a piece by [[Jane O'Reilly]]]] {{Feminism sidebar}} {{Economic systems sidebar}} {{Critique of political economy sidebar}} '''Feminist economics''' is the critical study of [[economics]] and economies, with a focus on gender-aware and inclusive economic inquiry and policy analysis.<ref name="IAFFE">{{Cite web|url=http://www.iaffe.org/pages/about-iaffe/miss/|title=IAFFE - Mission Statement|website=www.iaffe.org|language=en|access-date=2018-08-01|archive-date=2019-05-10|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190510115552/http://www.iaffe.org/pages/about-iaffe/miss/|url-status=dead}}</ref> Feminist economic researchers include academics, activists, policy theorists, and practitioners.<ref name="IAFFE" /> Much feminist economic research focuses on topics that have been neglected in the field, such as [[care work]], intimate partner violence, or on economic theories which could be improved through better incorporation of gendered effects and interactions, such as between paid and unpaid sectors of economies.<ref>{{Cite book|title=Feminist economics|date=2011|publisher=Edward Elgar|others=Benería, Lourdes., May, Ann Mari, 1956-, Strassmann, Diana Louise.|isbn=9781843765684|location=Cheltenham, UK|oclc=436265344}}</ref> Other feminist scholars have engaged in new forms of [[data collection]] and measurement such as the [[Gender Empowerment Measure]] (GEM), and more gender-aware theories such as the [[capabilities approach]].<ref name="intro">{{cite book|last1=Benería|first1=Lourdes|last2=May|first2=Ann Mari|last3=Strassmann|first3=Diana L.|author-link1=Lourdes Benería|title=Feminist Economics: Volume 1|year=2009|publisher=Edward Elgar|isbn=9781843765684|chapter=Introduction|location=Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA|chapter-url=https://www.e-elgar.co.uk/bookentry_main.lasso?id=3226|url-status = dead|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130527114151/https://www.e-elgar.co.uk/bookentry_main.lasso?id=3226|archive-date=2013-05-27}}</ref> Feminist economics is oriented toward the social ecology of money. Feminist economists call attention to the [[social construction]]s of traditional economics, questioning the extent to which it is [[positive economics|positive]] and [[objectivity (philosophy)|objective]], and showing how its models and methods are biased by an exclusive attention to [[masculine]]-associated topics and a one-sided favoring of masculine-associated assumptions and methods.<ref name="beyond">{{cite book|last1=Ferber|first1=Marianne A.|author-link1=Marianne Ferber|title=Feminist Economics Today: Beyond Economic Man|year=2003|publisher=Univ. of Chicago Press |location= Chicago |isbn= 978-0-226-24206-4 |pages=1–32 |chapter-url= https://books.google.com/books?id=ziv8m0ihvYAC&q=Beyond%20Economic%20Man%3A%20Ten%20Years%20Later&pg=PT14|author2=Nelson, Julie A.|author2-link=Julie A. Nelson|chapter=Beyond Economic Man, Ten Years Later}}</ref><ref name="nelson1">{{cite journal |last=Nelson|first=Julie A.|author-link=Julie A. Nelson|title=Feminism and Economics|journal=The Journal of Economic Perspectives|date=Spring 1995|volume=9 |issue=2 |pages=131–148 |jstor=2138170 |doi=10.1257/jep.9.2.131|url=http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/jep.9.2.131}}</ref> While economics traditionally focused on markets and masculine-associated ideas of autonomy, abstraction and logic, feminist economists call for a fuller exploration of economic life, including such "culturally [[feminine]]" topics such as [[family economics]], and examining the importance of connections, concreteness, and emotion in explaining economic phenomena.<ref name="beyond" /> Many scholars including [[Ester Boserup]], [[Marianne Ferber]], [[Drucilla K. Barker]], [[Julie A. Nelson]], [[Marilyn Waring]], [[Nancy Folbre]], [[Diane Elson]], [[Barbara Bergmann]] and [[Ailsa McKay]] have contributed to feminist economics. Waring's 1988 book ''[[If Women Counted]]'' is often regarded as the "founding document" of the discipline.<ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.bloomberg.com/news/2013-06-18/women-unaccounted-for-in-global-economy-proves-waring-influence.html |title=Women Unaccounted for in Global Economy Proves Waring Influence |last1=Langeland |first1=Terje |date=18 June 2013 |publisher=[[Bloomberg L.P.|Bloomberg]] |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130622033219/http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2013-06-18/women-unaccounted-for-in-global-economy-proves-waring-influence.html |access-date=18 June 2013 |archive-date=22 June 2013 |url-status = dead}}</ref><ref name="Nelson2014" /> By the 1990s feminist economics had become sufficiently recognised as an established subfield within economics to generate book and article publication opportunities for its practitioners.<ref name="peterson"/> ==Origins and history== Early on, [[feminist]] [[ethicist]]s, [[economists]], [[political scientists]], and [[systems scientists]] argued that [[women's work|women's traditional work]] (e.g. child-raising, caring for sick elders) and occupations (e.g. nursing, teaching) are systematically undervalued with respect to that of men. For example, [[Jane Jacobs]]' thesis of the "[[Guardian Ethic]]" and its contrast to the "[[Trader Ethic]]" sought to explain the undervaluing of guardianship activity, including the child-protecting, nurturing, and healing tasks that were traditionally assigned to women. Written in 1969 and later published in the ''Houseworker's Handbook'', Betsy Warrior's ''Housework: Slavery or a Labor of Love and The Source of Leisure Time''<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www2.cambridgema.gov/Historic/CWHP/bios_w.html|title=Cambridge Women's Heritage Project Database, W|website=www2.cambridgema.gov|access-date=2021-04-09|archive-date=2017-08-27|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170827210414/http://www2.cambridgema.gov/Historic/CWHP/bios_w.html|url-status=dead}}</ref> presents a cogent argument that the production and reproduction of domestic labor performed by women constitutes the foundation of all economic transactions and survival; although, unremunerated and not included in the GDP.<ref>Radical Feminism: A Documentary Reader, By Barbara A. Crow, Housework: Slavery or a Labor of Love, p 530, NYU Press 2000</ref> According to Warrior: "Economics, as it's presented today, lacks any basis in reality as it leaves out the very foundation of economic life. That foundation is built on women's labor; first her reproductive labor which produces every new laborer (and the first commodity, which is mother's milk and which sustains every new consumer/laborer); secondly, women's labor entails environmentally necessary cleaning, cooking to make raw materials consumable, negotiating to maintain social stability and nurturing, which prepares for market and maintains each laborer. This constitutes women's continuing industry enabling laborers to occupy every position in the work force. Without this fundamental labor and commodity there would be no economic activity nor we would have survived to continue to evolve."<ref>http://www.ncdsv.org/images/BH_Modest-Herstory-of-Besty-Warrior_8-2013.pdf {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20151120132516/http://www.ncdsv.org/images/BH_Modest-Herstory-of-Besty-Warrior_8-2013.pdf |date=2015-11-20 }} {{Bare URL PDF|date=March 2022}}</ref> Warrior also notes that the unacknowledged income of men from illegal activities like arms, drugs and human trafficking, political graft, religious emoluments and various other undisclosed activities provide a rich revenue stream to men, which further invalidates GDP figures.<ref>Houseworker's Handbook, Slavery or a Labor of love and The Source of Leisure Time, 1972</ref> Even in underground economies where women predominate numerically, like trafficking in humans, prostitution and domestic servitude, only a tiny fraction of the pimp's revenue filters down to the women and children he deploys. Usually the amount spent on them is merely for the maintenance of their lives and, in the case of those prostituted, some money may be spent on clothing and such accouterments as will make them more salable to the pimp's clients. For instance, focusing on just the US, according to a government sponsored report by the Urban Institute in 2014, "A street prostitute in Dallas may make as little as $5 per sex act. But pimps can take in $33,000 a week in Atlanta, where the sex business brings in an estimated $290 million per year."<ref>{{cite news|url=https://www.nytimes.com/2014/03/12/us/in-depth-report-details-economics-of-sex-trade.html|title=In-Depth Report Details Economics of Sex Trade|first=Annie|last=Lowrey|date=12 March 2014|newspaper=The New York Times}}</ref> Warrior believes that only an inclusive, facts-based economic analysis will provide a reliable bases for future planning for environmental and reproductive/population needs. In 1970, [[Ester Boserup]] published ''Woman's Role in Economic Development'' and provided the first systematic examination of the gendered effects of agricultural transformation, [[industrialization]] and other structural changes.<ref>{{cite book|last=Boserup|first=Ester|title=Woman's Role in Economic Development|year=1970|publisher=St. Martin's Press|location=New York|isbn=978-1-84407-392-4|author-link=Ester Boserup |url= https://books.google.com/books?id=EzXxQOf77K0C&pg=PP1}}</ref> This evidence illuminated the negative outcomes that these changes had for women. This work, among others, laid the basis for the broad claim that "women and men weather the storm of macroeconomic shocks, neoliberal policies, and the forces of globalization in different ways."<ref name="berik">{{Citation|last1=Berik|first1=Günseli|title=Feminist economics|pages=Vol III, Part 1, B.12|year=2011|editor-last1=Benería|editor-first1=Lourdes|contribution=Engendering development strategies and macroeconomic policies: what's sound and sensible?|location=Cheltenham, UK Northampton, Massachusetts|publisher=Edward Elgar|isbn=9781843765684|last2=Rodgers|first2=Yana van der Meulen|editor-last2=May|editor-first2=Ann Mari|editor-last3=Strassmann|editor-first3=Diana L|editor-link1=Lourdes Benería}} [http://www.unrisd.org/80256B3C005BCCF9/(httpAuxPages)/91E1E3A0620D9D72C12578D5005447DA/$file/1BerikRodgers.pdf (Pdf version).]</ref> Moreover, measures such as [[employment equity]] were implemented in [[developed nation]]s in the 1970s to 1990s, but these were not entirely successful in removing wage gaps even in nations with strong equity traditions. [[File:MarilynWaring2012.jpg|thumb|[[Marilyn Waring]], author of ''[[If Women Counted]]'' (1988)]] In 1988, [[Marilyn Waring]] published ''[[If Women Counted|If Women Counted: A New Feminist Economics]]'', a groundbreaking and systematic critique of the system of [[national accounts]], the international standard of measuring economic growth, and the ways in which women's unpaid work as well as the value of [[Nature]] have been excluded from what counts as productive in the economy. In the foreword to the 2014 anthology ''[[If Women Counted#Counting on Marilyn Waring: New Advances in Feminist Economics|Counting on Marilyn Waring]]'', [[Julie A. Nelson]] wrote: :"Marilyn Waring's work woke people up. She showed exactly how the unpaid work traditionally done by women has been made invisible within national accounting systems, and the damage this causes. Her book ... encouraged and influenced a wide range of work on ways, both numerical and otherwise, of valuing, preserving, and rewarding the work of care that sustains our lives. By pointing to a similar neglect of the natural environment, she also issued a wake-up call to issues of ecological sustainability that have only grown more pressing over time. In recent decades, the field of feminist economics has broadened and widened to encompass these topics and more."<ref name="Nelson2014">{{cite book|last=Nelson|first=Julie A.|author-link=Julie A. Nelson|editor1-last=Bjørnholt|editor1-first =Margunn|editor1-link=Margunn Bjørnholt|editor2-last=McKay|editor2-first =Ailsa|editor2-link=Ailsa McKay|title=Counting on Marilyn Waring: New Advances in Feminist Economics|year=2014|location=Bradford|publisher=[[Demeter Press]]|pages=ix–x|chapter=Foreword|isbn=9781927335277|chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Sbh8AwAAQBAJ&pg=PR9}}</ref> Supported by formation of the Committee on the Status of Women in the Economics Profession (CSWEP) in 1972, gender-based critiques of traditional economics appeared in the 1970s and 80s. The subsequent emergence of [[Development Alternatives with Women for a New Era]] (DAWN) and the 1992 founding of the [[#Heading International Association for Feminist Economics|International Association for Feminist Economics (IAFFE)]] along with its journal ''[[Feminist Economics (journal)|Feminist Economics]]'' in 1994<ref name="intro"/><ref name="beyond" /> encouraged the rapid growth of feminist economics. As in other disciplines, the initial emphasis of feminist economists was to critique the established theory, methodology, and policy approaches. The critique began in [[microeconomics]] of the household and [[labor markets]] and spread to [[macroeconomics]] and [[international trade]], ultimately extending to all areas of traditional economic analysis.<ref name="peterson">{{cite book | last1 = Peterson | first1 = Janice | last2 = Lewis | first2 = Margaret | title = The Elgar companion to feminist economics | publisher = Edward Elgar | location = Cheltenham, UK Northampton, MA | year = 1999 | isbn = 9781858984537 }}</ref> Feminist economists pushed for and produced gender aware theory and analysis, broadened the focus on economics and sought pluralism of methodology and research methods. Feminist economics shares many of its perspectives with [[ecological economics]] and the more applied field of [[green economy]], including the focus on [[sustainability]], [[nature]], justice and care values.<ref>{{cite book|last1=Aslaksen|first1=Iulie|author-link1=Iulie Aslaksen|last2=Bragstad|first2=Torunn|last3=Ås|first3=Berit|author-link3=Berit Ås|editor1-last=Bjørnholt|editor1-first =Margunn|editor1-link=Margunn Bjørnholt|editor2-last=McKay|editor2-first =Ailsa|editor2-link=Ailsa McKay|title=Counting on Marilyn Waring: New Advances in Feminist Economics|year=2014|location=Bradford|publisher=[[Demeter Press]]|chapter=Feminist Economics as Vision for a Sustainable Future|pages=21–36|isbn=9781927335277|chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Sbh8AwAAQBAJ&pg=PA21}}</ref> ==Critiques of traditional economics== Although there is no definitive list of the principles of feminist economics, feminist economists offer a variety of critiques of standard approaches in economics.<ref name="web">{{cite web |last1=Schneider |first1=Geoff |last2=Shackelford |first2=Jean |author-link2=Jean Shackelford |url=http://www.facstaff.bucknell.edu/gschnedr/FemPrcpls.htm |title=Ten Principles of Feminist Economics: A Modestly Proposed Antidote |publisher=Dept. of Economics, Bucknell University |access-date=2012-06-20 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120630022557/http://www.facstaff.bucknell.edu/gschnedr/FemPrcpls.htm |archive-date=2012-06-30 |url-status = dead}}</ref> For example, prominent feminist economist [[Paula England]] provided one of the earliest feminist critiques of traditional economics as she challenged the claims that: *That interpersonal [[utility]] comparisons are impossible; *That tastes are [[exogenous variable|exogenous]] and unchanging; *That actors are selfish; and *That household heads act altruistically.<ref name="separative">{{cite book|last=England|first=Paula|title=Beyond Economic Man: Feminist Theory and Economics|year=1994|publisher=Univ. of Chicago Press|location=Chicago [u.a.]|isbn=978-0-226-24201-9|pages=37–43|chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=BFg6lK48EX0C&q=The%20Separative%20Self%3A%20Androcentric%20Bias%20in%20Neoclassical%20Assumptions&pg=PA37|chapter=The Separative Self: Androcentric Bias in Neoclassical Assumptions}}</ref> This list is not exhaustive but does represent some of the central feminist economic critiques of traditional economics, out of the wide variety of such viewpoints and critiques. ===Normativity=== Many feminists call attention to value judgments in economic analysis.<ref name="nelson1" /> This idea is contrary to the typical conception of economics as a [[positivism|positive science]] held by many practitioners. For example, Geoff Schneider and [[Jean Shackelford]] suggest that, as in other sciences,<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Franklin |first=Sarah |date=1995 |title=Science as Culture, Cultures of Science |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/2155934 |journal=Annual Review of Anthropology |volume=24 |pages=163–184 |doi=10.1146/annurev.an.24.100195.001115 |jstor=2155934 |issn=0084-6570}}</ref> "the issues that economists choose to study, the kinds of questions they ask, and the type of analysis undertaken all are a product of a belief system which is influenced by numerous factors, some of them ideological in character."<ref name="web" /> Similarly, Diana Strassmann comments, "All economic [[statistics]] are based on an underlying story forming the basis of the definition. In this way, narrative constructions necessarily underlie all definitions of variables and statistics. Therefore, economic research cannot escape being inherently qualitative, regardless of how it is labeled."<ref name="strassmann">{{cite journal|last=Strassmann|first=Diana|title=Editorial: Expanding the Methodological Boundaries of Economics|journal=Feminist Economics|date=20 January 1997|volume=3|issue=2|pages=vii–ix |doi=10.1080/135457097338771a}}</ref> Feminist economists call attention to the [[value judgement]]s in all aspects economics and criticize its depiction of an objective science. ===Free trade=== A central principle of mainstream economics is that [[trade]] can make everyone better off through [[comparative advantage]] and efficiency gains from specialization and greater efficiency.<ref name=manikiw>{{cite book|last=Mankiw|first=N. Gregory|author-link=Greg Mankiw|title=Principles of Economics|year=1997|publisher=Dryden Press|location=Fort Worth, TX|isbn=9780030982385 |url= https://archive.org/details/principlesofmicr00greg|url-access=registration|quote=comparative advantage.}}</ref><ref name="elson">{{cite book|last=Elson |first=Diane|author-link=Diane Elson|title=Feminist Economics of Trade|year=2007|publisher=Routledge|location=New York|isbn=978-0-415-77059-0|pages=33–48|chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=SkWUSDW244gC&q=Mainstream%2C%20Heterodox%20and%20Feminist%20Trade%20Theory&pg=PA33 |author2=Grown, Caren |author3=Cagatay, Nilufer |chapter=Mainstream, Heterodox and Feminist Trade Theory}}</ref> Many feminist economists question this claim. [[Diane Elson]], [[Caren Grown]] and [[Nilufer Cagatay]] explore the role that gender inequalities play in international trade and how such trade reshapes gender inequality itself. They and other feminist economists explore whose interests specific trade practices serve. For example, they may highlight that in [[Africa]], specialization in the cultivation of a single [[cash crop]] for export in many countries made those countries extremely vulnerable to price fluctuations, weather patterns, and pests.<ref name="web" /> Feminist economists may also consider the specific gendered effects of trade-decisions. For instance, "in countries such as [[Kenya]], men generally controlled the earnings from cash crops while women were still expected to provide food and clothing for the household, their traditional role in the African family, along with labor to produce cash crops. Thus women suffered significantly from the transition away from subsistence food production towards specialization and trade."<ref name="web" /> Similarly, since women often lack economic power as business owners, they are more likely to be hired as cheap labor, often involving them in exploitative situations.<ref name="elson"/> These examples highlight feminist economic theory's critique of the traditional economic theory. ===Exclusion of non-market activity=== Feminist economics call attention to the importance of non-market activities, such as [[childcare]] and [[domestic work]], to economic development.<ref name="Power, Marilyn 2011">{{cite journal|last=Power|first=Marilyn|title=Social Provisioning as a Starting Point for Feminist Economics|journal=[[Feminist Economics (journal)|Feminist Economics]]|date=November 2004|volume=10|issue=3|pages=3–19|doi=10.1080/1354570042000267608|s2cid=145130126}}</ref><ref name="razavi">{{cite journal|last=Razavi|first=Shahra|title=From Global Economic Crisis to the 'Other Crisis'|journal=[[Development (journal)|Development]]|date=September 2009|volume=52|issue=3|pages=323–328|doi=10.1057/dev.2009.33|s2cid=83754064}}</ref> This stands in sharp contrast to [[neoclassical economics]] where those forms of labor are unaccounted for as "non-economic" phenomena.<ref name="nelson1"/> Including such labor in economic accounts removes substantial gender bias because women disproportionately perform those tasks.<ref>{{cite book|title=Human Development Report 1995|chapter-url=http://hdr.undp.org/en/media/hdr_1995_en_chap4.pdf|pages=87–98|year=1995|chapter=Valuing women's work |publisher=[[United Nations Development Programme]]}}</ref> When that labor is unaccounted for in economic models, much work done by women is ignored, literally devaluing their effort. [[File:Trabajadora doméstico.JPG|thumb|A Colombian domestic worker. Neighborhood friends and family sharing household and childcare responsibilities is an example of non-market activity performed outside of the traditional [[labor market]].]] More specifically, for example, [[Nancy Folbre]] examines the role of [[children]] as [[public goods]] and how the non-market labor of parents contributes to the development of [[human capital]] as a [[public service]].<ref>{{cite journal|last=Folbre|first=Nancy|author-link=Nancy Folbre|title=Children as Public Goods|journal=[[The American Economic Review]]|date=May 1994|volume=84|issue=2|pages=86–90|jstor=2117807}}</ref> In this sense, children are [[positive externality]] which is under-invested according to traditional analysis. Folbre indicates that this oversight partially results from failing to properly examine non-market activities. [[Marilyn Waring]] described how the exclusion of non-market activities in the [[national accounts|national accounting systems]] relied on the deliberate choice and the design of the international standard of national accounts that explicitly excluded non-market activities. In some countries, such as [[Norway]], which had included unpaid household work in the GDP in the first half of the 20th century, it was left out in 1950 for reasons of compatibility with the new international standard.<ref>{{cite book|last1=Aslaksen|first1=Iulie|author-link1=Iulie Aslaksen|last2=Koren|first2=Charlotte|editor1-last=Bjørnholt|editor1-first =Margunn|editor1-link=Margunn Bjørnholt|editor2-last=McKay|editor2-first =Ailsa|editor2-link=Ailsa McKay|title=Counting on Marilyn Waring: New Advances in Feminist Economics|year=2014|location=Bradford|publisher=[[Demeter Press]]|pages=57–71|chapter=Reflections on Unpaid Household Work, Economic Growth, and Consumption Possibilities|isbn=9781927335277|chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Sbh8AwAAQBAJ&pg=PA57}}</ref> [[Ailsa McKay]] argues for a [[basic income]] as "a tool for promoting gender-neutral social citizenship rights" partially to address these concerns.<ref>{{cite journal | last1 = McKay | first1 = Ailsa | author-link1 = Ailsa McKay | year =2001 | title = Rethinking Work and Income Maintenance Policy: Promoting Gender Equality Through a Citizens' Basic Income | journal = [[Feminist Economics (journal)|Feminist Economics]] | volume = 7 | issue = 1 | pages = 97–118 | doi = 10.1080/13545700010022721 | s2cid = 153865511 }}</ref> ===Omission of power relations=== Feminist economics often assert that power relations exist within the economy, and therefore, must be assessed in economic models in ways that they previously have been overlooked.<ref name="Power, Marilyn 2011"/> For example, in "neoclassical texts, the sale of labor is viewed as a mutually beneficial exchange that benefits both parties. No mention is made of the power inequities in the exchange which tend to give the employer power over the employee."<ref name="web" /> These power relations often favor men and there is "never any mention made of the particular difficulties that confront females in the [[Gender inequality#In the workplace|workplace]]."<ref name="web" /> Consequently, "Understanding power and [[patriarchy]] helps us to analyze how men-dominated economic institutions function and why females are often at a disadvantage in the workplace."<ref name="web" /> Feminist economists often extend these criticisms to many aspects of the social world, arguing that power relations are an endemic and important feature of society. ===Omission of gender and race=== Feminist economics argue that [[gender]] and [[race (classification of humans)|race]] must be considered in economic analysis. [[Amartya Sen]] argues that "the systematically inferior position of women inside and outside the household in many societies points to the necessity of treating gender as a force of its own in development analysis."<ref name="sen_gender">{{cite journal|last=Sen|first=Amartya|title=Gender and Cooperative Conflicts|date=July 1987|volume=1987/18|series=Working Papers|url=http://www.wider.unu.edu/publications/working-papers/previous/en_GB/wp-18/_files/82530817554384479/default/WP18.pdf|publisher=UNU-WIDER|access-date=2012-06-20|archive-date=2017-10-26|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171026115251/https://www.wider.unu.edu/publications/working-papers/previous/en_GB/wp-18/_files/82530817554384479/default/WP18.pdf|url-status=dead}}</ref> He goes on to say that experiences of men and women, even within the same household, are often so different that examining economics without gender can be misleading. Economic models can often be improved by explicitly considering gender, race, class, and [[caste]].<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Brewer|first1=Rose M.|last2=Conrad|first2=Cecilia A.|last3=King|first3=Mary C.|author-link2=Cecilia Conrad |title=The Complexities and Potential of Theorizing Gender, Caste, Race, and Class|journal=Feminist Economics|date=January 2002|volume=8|issue=2|pages=3–17|doi=10.1080/1354570022000019038|s2cid=143046656}}</ref> Julie Matthaie describes their importance: "Not only did gender and racial-ethnic differences and inequality precede [[capitalism]], they have been built into it in key ways. In other words, every aspect of our capitalist economy is gendered and racialized; a theory and practice that ignores this is inherently flawed."<ref>{{cite journal|last=Matthaei|first=Julie|title=Why feminist, Marxist, and anti-racist economists should be feminist–Marxist–anti-racist economists|journal=Feminist Economics|date=March 1996|volume=2|issue=1|pages=22–42|doi=10.1080/738552684}}</ref> Feminist economist Eiman Zein-Elabdin says racial and gender differences should be examined since both have traditionally been ignored and thus are equally described as "feminist difference."<ref>{{cite book|last=Zein-Elabdin|first=Eiman|title=Toward a Feminist Philosophy of Economics|year=2003|publisher=Taylor & Francis|location=London|isbn=978-0-415-28388-5|pages=321–333|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=xXt6Ks1f0xcC&q=The%20Difficulty%20of%20Feminist%20Economics&pg=PA321|editor=Barker, Drucilla K.}}</ref> The July 2002 issue of the ''[[Feminist Economics (journal)|Feminist Economics]]'' journal was dedicated to issues of "gender, color, caste and class."<ref name="Power, Marilyn 2011"/> ===Exaggeration of gender differences=== In other cases gender differences have been exaggerated, potentially encouraging unjustified stereotyping. In recent works<ref>[[Julie A. Nelson]] (2015) "Are Women Really More Risk-Averse than Men? A Re-Analysis of the Literature Using Expanded Methods." ''Journal of Economic Surveys'' '''29'''(3): 566-585, doi: 10.1111/joes.12069; (2014) "The Power of Stereotyping and Confirmation Bias to Overwhelm Accurate Assessment: The Case of Economics, Gender, and Risk Aversion." ''Journal of Economic Methodology'' '''21'''(3): 211-231, doi: 10.1080/1350178X.2014.939691; and (2015) "Not-So-Strong Evidence for Gender Differences in Risk Taking," ''Feminist Economics'', doi: OI:10.1080/13545701.2015.1057609</ref> [[Julie A. Nelson]] has shown how the idea that "women are more risk averse than men," a now-popular assertion from behavioral economics, actually rests on extremely thin empirical evidence. Conducting meta-analyses of recent studies, she demonstrates that, while statistically significant differences in measures of mean risk aversion are sometimes found, the substantive size of these group-level differences tend to be small (on the order of a fraction of a standard deviation), and many other studies fail to find a statistically significant difference at all. Yet the studies that fail to find "difference" are less likely to be published or highlighted. In addition, claims that men and women have "different" preferences (such as for risk, competition, or altruism) often tend to be misinterpreted as categorical, that is, as applying to all women and all men, as individuals. In fact, small differences in average behavior, such as are found in some studies, are generally accompanied by large overlaps in men's and women's distributions. That is, both men and women can generally be found in the most risk-averse (or competitive or altruistic) groups, as well as in the least. ===''Homo economicus''=== The [[neoclassical economics|neoclassical economic]] model of a person is called ''[[Homo economicus]]'', describing a person who "interacts in society without being influenced by society," because "his mode of interaction is through an ideal [[Market (economics)|market]]," in which prices are the only necessary considerations.<ref name="nelson1" /> In this view, people are considered rational actors who engage in [[marginal analysis]] to make many or all of their decisions.<ref name="web" /> Feminist economists argue that people are more complex than such models, and call for "a more holistic vision of an economic actor, which includes group interactions and actions motivated by factors other than greed."<ref name="web" /> Feminist economics holds that such a reformation provides a better description of the actual experiences of both men and women in the market, arguing that mainstream economics overemphasizes the role of individualism, competition and selfishness of all actors. Instead, feminist economists like [[Nancy Folbre]] show that cooperation also plays a role in the economy. Feminist economists also point out that [[agency (sociology)|agency]] is not available to everyone, such as children, the sick, and the frail elderly. Responsibilities for their care can compromise the agency of caregivers as well. This is a critical departure from the ''homo economicus'' model.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Levison|first=Deborah|title=Children as Economic Agents|journal=Feminist Economics|date=January 2000|volume=6|issue=1|pages=125–134|doi=10.1080/135457000337732|citeseerx=10.1.1.460.2185|s2cid=154879275}}</ref> Moreover, feminist economists critique the focus of neoclassical economics on monetary rewards. [[Nancy Folbre]] notes, "legal rules and cultural norms can affect market outcomes in ways distinctly disadvantageous to women." This includes [[occupational segregation]] resulting in unequal pay for women. Feminist research in these areas contradicts the neoclassical description of [[labor markets]] in which [[Job (role)|occupations]] are chosen freely by individuals acting alone and out of their own free will.<ref name="web" /> Feminist economics also includes study of [[Norm (social)|norms]] relevant to economics, challenging the traditional view that material incentives will reliably provide the goods we want and need (consumer sovereignty), which does not hold true for many people. [[Institutional economics]] is one means by which feminist economists improve upon the ''homo economicus'' model. This theory examines the role of institutions and evolutionary social processes in shaping economic behavior, emphasizing "the complexity of human motives and the importance of culture and relations of power." This provides a more holistic view of the economic actor than ''homo economicus.''<ref name="Power, Marilyn 2011"/> The work of George Akerlof and Janet Yellen on [[efficiency wage]]s based on notions of fairness provides an example of a feminist model of economic actors. In their work, agents are not hyperrational or isolated, but instead act in concert and with fairness, are capable of experiencing jealousy, and are interested in personal relationships. This work is based on empirical [[sociology]] and psychology, and suggests that wages can be influenced by fairness considerations rather than purely market forces.<ref name="nelson1" /> ===Limited methodology=== Economics is often thought of as "the study of how society manages its [[scarce resources]]" and as such is limited to mathematical inquiry.<ref name="nelson1"/><ref name=manikiw/> Traditional economists often say such an approach assures objectivity and separates economics from "softer" fields such as [[sociology]] and [[political science]]. Feminist economists, argue on the contrary that a mathematical conception of economics limited to scarce resources is a holdover from the early years of science and [[Cartesian philosophy]], and limits economic analysis. So feminist economists often call for more diverse data collection and broader economic models.<ref name="nelson1"/> ===Economic pedagogy=== Feminist economists suggest that both the content and teaching style of economics courses would benefit from certain changes. Some recommend including experimental learning, laboratory sessions, individual research and more chances to "do economics."<ref name="nelson1"/> Some want more dialogue between instructors and students. Many feminist economists are urgently interested in how course content influences the demographic composition of future economists, suggesting that the "classroom climate" affects some students' perceptions of their own ability.<ref name="hall">{{cite journal|author1=Hall, Roberta M. |author2=Sandler, Bernice R. |title=The Classroom Climate: A Chilly One for Women?|date=February 1982|url=http://www.aacu.org/psew/publications/Classroom_Climate_ChilyOne.pdf|publisher=Project on the Status and Education of Women, Association of American Colleges|url-status = dead|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20121003175716/http://aacu.org/psew/publications/Classroom_Climate_ChilyOne.pdf|archive-date=2012-10-03}}</ref> ===2008 financial crisis=== [[Margunn Bjørnholt]] and [[Ailsa McKay]] argue that the [[2008 financial crisis]] and the response to it revealed a crisis of ideas in mainstream economics and within the economics profession, and call for a reshaping of both the economy, economic theory and the economics profession. They argue that such a reshaping should include new advances within feminist economics that take as their starting point the socially responsible, sensible and accountable subject in creating an economy and economic theories that fully acknowledge care for each other as well as the planet.<ref>{{cite book|last1=Bjørnholt|first1=Margunn|author1-link=Margunn Bjørnholt|last2=McKay|first2=Ailsa|author2-link=Ailsa McKay|editor1-last=Bjørnholt|editor1-first =Margunn|editor1-link=Margunn Bjørnholt|editor2-last=McKay|editor2-first =Ailsa|editor2-link=Ailsa McKay|title=Counting on Marilyn Waring: New Advances in Feminist Economics|chapter-url=http://www.margunnbjornholt.no/wp-content/uploads/2014/05/Advances-in-Feminist-Economics-in-Times-of-Economic-Crisis.pdf|year=2014|location=Bradford|publisher=[[Demeter Press]]|pages=7–20|chapter=Advances in Feminist Economics in Times of Economic Crisis|isbn=9781927335277}}</ref> ==Major areas of inquiry== ===Economic epistemology=== Feminist critiques of economics include that "economics, like any science, is [[Social constructionism|socially constructed]]."<ref name="nelson1"/> Feminist economists say that social constructs act to [[Privilege (social inequality)|privilege]] male-identified, [[western culture|western]], and [[heterosexual]] interpretations of economics.<ref name="intro"/> They generally incorporate [[feminist theory]] and frameworks to show how traditional economics communities signal expectations regarding appropriate participants, to the exclusion of outsiders. Such criticisms extend to the theories, methodologies and research areas of economics, in order to show that accounts of economic life are deeply influenced by biased histories, social structures, norms, cultural practices, interpersonal interactions, and politics.<ref name="intro"/> Feminist economists often make a critical distinction that masculine bias in economics is primarily a result of [[gender]], not [[sex]].<ref name="nelson1"/> In other words, when feminist economists highlight the biases of mainstream economics, they focus on its social beliefs about masculinity like objectivity, separation, logical consistency, individual accomplishment, mathematics, abstraction, and lack of emotion, but not on the gender of authorities and subjects. However, the over-representation of men among economists and their subjects of study is also a concern. ===Economic history=== [[File:US womens earnings as a percentage of mens 1979-2005.svg|thumb|right|Women's weekly earnings as a percentage of men's in the U.S. by age, 1979-2005]] Feminist economists say that [[mainstream economics]] has been disproportionately developed by European-descended, [[heterosexual]], middle and upper-middle-class men, and that this has led to suppression of the life experiences of the full diversity of the world's people, especially women, children and those in non-traditional families.<ref>{{cite book|last=Strassmann|first=Diana|title=Out of the Margin: Feminist Perspectives on Economics|year=1997|publisher=Routledge|location=London [u.a.]|isbn=978-0-415-12575-8|pages=94–104|chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=hF_Jm7bHOysC&q=The%20Economist%20as%20Storyteller%3A%20What%20the%20Texts%20Reveal&pg=PA94|author2=Polanyi, Livia|chapter=The Economist as Storyteller}}</ref> Additionally, feminist economists claim that the historical bases of economics are inherently exclusionary to women. [[Michèle Pujol]] points to five specific historical assumptions about women that arose, became embedded in the formulation of economics, and continue to be used to maintain that women are different from the masculinized norms and exclude them.<ref>{{cite book|last=Pujol|first=Michele|author-link=Michèle Pujol|title=Out of the Margin: Feminist Perspectives on Economics| year=1995| publisher=Routledge| location=London |isbn=9780415125314 |pages=17–30 |chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=nTtdGU3hfcEC&q=Into%20the%20Margin%20pujol&pg=PA17|chapter=Into the Margin!}}</ref> These include the ideas that: *All women are married, or if not yet, they will be and all women will have children. *All women are economically dependent on a male relative. *All women are (and should be) housewives due to their reproductive capacities. *Women are unproductive in the industrial workforce. *Women are irrational, unfit economic agents, and cannot be trusted to make the right economic decisions. Feminist economists also examine early economic thinkers' interaction or lack of interaction with gender and women's issues, showing examples of women's historical engagement with economic thought. For example, [[Edith Kuiper]] discusses [[Adam Smith|Adam Smith's]] engagement with feminist discourse on the role of women in the eighteenth century [[France]] and [[England]].<ref>{{cite book|last=Kuiper|first=Edith|author-link=Edith Kuiper|title=New Voices on Adam Smith|year=2006|publisher=Routledge|location=London|isbn=978-0-415-35696-1|pages=40–57|chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=7JN532ipBVwC&q=Adam%20Smith%20and%20his%20Feminist%20Contemporaries&pg=PA40|chapter=Adam Smith and his feminist contemporaries}}</ref> She finds that through his writings, Smith typically supported the ''[[status quo]]'' on women's issues and "lost sight of the division of labor in the family and the contribution of women's economic work." In response, she points to [[Mary Collier|Mary Collier's]] works such as ''The Woman's Labour'' (1739) to help understand Smith's contemporaneous experiences of women and fill in such gaps. ===Engendering macroeconomic theories=== [[File:OECD gender wage gap 2006.jpeg|thumb|Percentage gap between median men's and women's wages, for full-time workers by OECD country, 2006. In the U.K., the most significant factors associated with the remaining gender pay gap are part-time work, education, the size of the firm a person is employed in, and occupational segregation. (Women are under-represented in managerial and high-paying professional occupations.)<ref>{{Cite journal |first= Victoria |last= Thomson |date= October 2006 |title= How Much of the Remaining Gender Pay Gap is the Result of Discrimination, and How Much is Due to Individual Choices? |journal= International Journal of Urban Labour and Leisure |volume= 7 |issue= 2 |url= http://www.ijull.co.uk/vol7/2/thomson.pdf |access-date= September 26, 2012}}</ref>]] Central to feminist economics is an effort to alter the theoretical modeling of the economy, to reduce gender bias and inequity.<ref name="berik"/> Feminist [[macroeconomics|macroeconomic]] inquiries focus on international capital flows, fiscal austerity, deregulation and privatization, [[monetary policy]], [[international trade]] and more. In general, these modifications take three main forms: gender disaggregation, the addition of gender-based macroeconomic variables, and the creation of a two-sector system. ====Gender disaggregation==== This method of economic analysis seeks to overcome gender bias by showing how men and women differ in their consumption, investment or saving behavior. Gender disaggregation strategies justify the separation of macroeconomic variables by gender. Korkut Ertürk and Nilüfer Çağatay show how the feminization of labor stimulates investment, while an increase in female activity in housework raises savings.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Ertürk|first=Korkut|author2=Çağatay, Nilüfer|title=Macroeconomic consequences of cyclical and secular changes in feminization: An experiment at gendered macromodeling|journal=World Development|date=November 1995|volume=23|issue=11|pages=1969–1977|doi=10.1016/0305-750X(95)00090-Y}}</ref> This model highlights how gender effects macroeconomic variables and shows that economies have a higher likelihood of recovering from downturns if women participate in the labor force more, instead of devoting their time to housework.<ref name="berik"/> ====Gendered macroeconomic variables==== [[File:US womens earnings and employment by industry 2009.png|thumb|U.S. women's weekly earnings, employment, and percentage of men's earnings, by industry, 2009]] {{See also|Gender pay gap}} This approach demonstrates the effects of gender inequalities by enhancing macroeconomic models. Bernard Walters shows that traditional neoclassical models fail to adequately assess work related to reproduction by assuming that the population and labor are determined exogenously.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Walters|first=Bernard|title=Engendering macroeconomics: A reconsideration of growth theory|journal=World Development|date=November 1995|volume=23|issue=11|pages=1869–1880|doi=10.1016/0305-750X(95)00083-O|url=http://econpapers.repec.org/article/eeewdevel/v_3a23_3ay_3a1995_3ai_3a11_3ap_3a1869-1880.htm|citeseerx=10.1.1.475.293}}</ref> That fails to account for the fact that inputs are produced through caring labor, which is disproportionately performed by women. Stephen Knowels ''et al.'' use a neoclassical growth model to show that women's education has a positive [[statistically significant]] effect on [[labor productivity]], more robust than that of men's education.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Knowles|first=Stephen|author2=Lorgelly, Paula K.|author3=Owen, P. Dorian|title=Are educational gender gaps a brake on economic development? Some cross-country empirical evidence|journal=Oxford Economic Papers|date=January 2002|volume=54|issue=1|url=http://www4.fe.uc.pt/mapsd/knowleslorgellyowenoep02.pdf|pages=118–149|doi=10.1093/oep/54.1.118|access-date=2012-09-26|archive-date=2016-03-04|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160304025850/http://www4.fe.uc.pt/mapsd/knowleslorgellyowenoep02.pdf|url-status=dead}}</ref> In both of these cases, economists highlight and address the gender biases of macroeconomic variables to show that gender plays a significant role in models' outcomes. ====Two-sector system==== The two-sector system approach models the economy as two separate systems: one involving the standard macroeconomic variables, while the other includes gender-specific variables. [[Sandy Darity, Jr.|William Darity]] developed a two-sector approach for low-income, farm-based economies.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Darity|first=William|author-link=Sandy Darity, Jr.|title=The formal structure of a gender-segregated low-income economy|journal=World Development|date=November 1995|volume=23|issue=11|pages=1963–1968|doi=10.1016/0305-750X(95)00082-N}}</ref> Darity shows that [[subsistence economy|subsistence]] farming depended on the labor of women, while the production of income depended on the labor of both men and women in [[cash-crop]] activities. This model shows that when men control production and income, they seek to maximize income by persuading women to put additional effort into cash-crop production, causing increases in cash crops come at the expense of subsistence production.<ref name="berik"/> ===Well-being=== Many feminist economists argue economics should be focused less on mechanisms (like [[income]]) or theories (such as [[utilitarianism]]) and more on [[well-being]], a multidimensional concept including income, health, education, empowerment and social status.<ref name="berik"/><ref name="Power, Marilyn 2011"/> They argue that economic success can not be measured only by [[good (economics)|good]]s or [[gross domestic product]], but must also be measured by human well-being. Aggregate income is not sufficient to evaluate general well-being, because individual entitlements and needs must also be considered, leading feminist economists to study [[health]], longevity, access to [[property]], [[education]], and related factors.<ref name="intro" /><ref>{{cite journal|last=Hill|first=M. Anne|author2=King, Elizabeth|title=Women's education and economic well-being|journal=Feminist Economics|date=July 1995|volume=1|issue=2|pages=21–46|doi=10.1080/714042230}}</ref> [[Bina Agarwal]] and Pradeep Panda illustrate that a woman's property status (such as owning a house or land) directly and significantly reduces her chances of experiencing [[domestic violence]], while [[employment]] makes little difference.<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Agarwal|first1=Bina|author2=Panda, Pradeep|author-link1=Bina Agarwal|title=Toward Freedom from Domestic Violence: The Neglected Obvious|journal=Journal of Human Development|date=November 2007|volume=8|issue=3|pages=359–388|doi=10.1080/14649880701462171|s2cid=28511073}}</ref> They argue that such [[immovable property]] increases women's [[self-esteem]], economic security, and strengthens their fall-back positions, enhancing their options and bargaining clout. They show that property ownership is an important contributor to women's economic well-being because it reduces their susceptibility to violence. In order to measure well-being more generally, [[Amartya Sen]], [[Sakiko Fukuda-Parr]], and other feminist economists helped develop alternatives to [[Gross Domestic Product]], such as the [[Human Development Index]].<ref>{{cite journal|last=Fukuda-Parr|first=Sakiko|author-link=Sakiko Fukuda-Parr|title=The Human Development Paradigm: Operationalizing Sen's Ideas on Capabilities |journal=Feminist Economics|date=January 2003|volume=9|issue=2–3|pages=301–317|doi=10.1080/1354570022000077980|s2cid=18178004}}</ref> Other models of interest to feminist economists include the [[labor theory of value]], which was most thoroughly developed in ''Das Kapital'' by [[Karl Marx]]. That model considers production as a socially constructed human project and redefines wages as means to earning a living. This refocuses economic models on human innate desires and needs as opposed to monetary incentives.<ref name="Power, Marilyn 2011"/> ====Human capabilities approach==== {{main|Capabilities approach}} Economists [[Amartya Sen]] and Philosopher [[Martha Nussbaum]] created the [[capabilities approach|human capabilities approach]] as an alternative way to assess economic success rooted in the ideas of [[welfare economics]] and focused on the individual's potential to do and be what he or she may choose to value.<ref>{{cite book | last1 = Nussbaum | first1 = Martha | last2 = Sen | first2 = Amartya | author-link1 = Martha Nussbaum | author2-link = Amartya Sen | title = The Quality of life | publisher = Clarendon Press Oxford University Press | location=Oxford England New York | year=1993|isbn=9780198287971 }}</ref><ref>{{cite book | last = Alkire | first = Sabina | author-link = Sabina Alkire | title = Valuing freedoms: Sen's capability approach and poverty reduction | publisher = Oxford University Press | location = Oxford New York | year = 2005 | isbn = 9780199283316 }}</ref><ref>{{cite journal|last=Sen|first=Amartya|author-link=Amartya Sen|title=Development as Capability Expansion|journal=Journal of Development Planning|year=1989|volume=19|pages=41–58|url=http://tek.bke.hu/regikorok/sen/docs/development.pdf}}{{dead link|date=December 2017 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }}</ref> Unlike traditional economic measures of success, focused on [[GDP]], [[utility]], [[income]], [[asset]]s or other monetary measures, the capabilities approach focuses on what individuals are able to do. This approach emphasizes processes as well as outcomes, and draws attention to cultural, social and material dynamics of well-being. [[Martha Nussbaum]], expanded on the model with a more complete list of central capabilities including life, health, bodily integrity, thought, and more.<ref name="nussbaum">{{cite book | last = Nussbaum | first = Martha|author-link=Martha Nussbaum | title = Creating capabilities: the human development approach | publisher = The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press | location = Cambridge, Massachusetts | year = 2013 | isbn = 9780674072350 }}</ref><ref>{{cite journal|last=Nussbaum|first=Martha|author-link=Martha Nussbaum|title=Capabilities as Fundamental Entitlements: Sen and Social Justice |journal=Feminist Economics|date=January 2003|volume=9|issue=2–3 |pages=33–59 |doi=10.1080/1354570022000077926 |citeseerx=10.1.1.541.3425|s2cid=145798740}}</ref> In recent years, the capabilities approach has influenced the creation of new models including the UN's [[Human Development Index]] (HDI). ===Household bargaining=== Central to feminist economics is a different approach to the "family" and "household." In classical economics, those units are typically described as amicable and [[homogeneous]]. [[Gary Becker]] and new home economists introduced the study of "the family" to traditional economics, which usually assumes the family is a single, altruistic unit among which money is distributed equally. Others have concluded that an optimal distribution of commodities and provisions takes place within the family as a result of which they view families in the same manner as individuals.<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Samuelson|first1=Paul A.|title=Social Indifference Curves|journal=The Quarterly Journal of Economics|date=February 1956|volume=70|issue=1|pages=9–10|url=http://gatton.uky.edu/faculty/hoytw/751/articles/samuelsonsic.pdf|access-date=15 April 2015|doi=10.2307/1884510|jstor=1884510|url-status = dead|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20140909194253/http://gatton.uky.edu/faculty/hoytw/751/articles/samuelsonsic.pdf|archive-date=9 September 2014}}</ref> These models, according to feminist economists, "endorsed traditional expectations about the sexes," and applied individualistic rational-choice models to explain home behavior.<ref name="nelson1" /> Feminist economists modify these assumptions to account for exploitative sexual and gender relations, [[single-parent families]], [[same-sex relationships]], familial relations with children, and the consequences of reproduction. Specifically, feminist economists move beyond unitary household models and [[game theory]] to show the diversity of household experiences. For example, [[Bina Agarwal]] and others have critiqued the mainstream model and helped provide a better understanding of intra-household bargaining power.<ref name="agarwal">{{cite journal|last=Agarwal|first=Bina|author-link=Bina Agarwal|title=Bargaining and Gender Relations: Within and Beyond the Household|journal=Feminist Economics|date=Spring 1997|volume=3|issue=1|pages=1–51|url=http://www.binaagarwal.com/downloads/apapers/bagaining_and_gender_relations.pdf|doi=10.1080/135457097338799|citeseerx=10.1.1.472.6354}}</ref> Agarwal shows that a lack of power and outside options for women hinders their ability to negotiate within their families. [[Amartya Sen]] shows how social norms that devalue women's unpaid work in the household often disadvantage women in [[intra-household bargaining]]. These feminist economists argue that such claims have important economic outcomes which must be recognized within economic frameworks. ===Care economy=== {{main|Care Work}} Feminist economists join the [[United Nations|UN]] and others in acknowledging [[care work]], as a kind of [[Labor (economics)|work]] which includes all tasks involving [[caregiving]], as central to economic development and human well-being.<ref name="razavi"/><ref>{{cite journal|last=Folbre|first=Nancy|author-link=Nancy Folbre|title='Holding Hands at Midnight': The Paradox of Caring Labor|journal=Feminist Economics|date=March 1995|volume=1|issue=1|pages=73–92|doi=10.1080/714042215|url=https://ideas.repec.org/a/taf/femeco/v1y1995i1p73-92.html}}</ref><ref>{{cite book|title=Human Development Report 1999|chapter-url=http://hdr.undp.org/en/media/hdr_1999_ch3.pdf|pages=77–83|year=1999|chapter=The Invisible Heart – Care and the Global Economy |publisher=United Nations Development Programme}}</ref> Feminist economists study both paid and unpaid care work. They argue that traditional analysis of economics often ignores the value of household unpaid work. Feminist economists have argued that unpaid [[domestic work]] is as valuable as paid work, so measures of economic success should include unpaid work. They have shown that women are disproportionately responsible for performing such care work.<ref>{{cite book|last1=Chen|first1=Martha|author-link1=Martha Chen|title=Progress of the World's Women 2005: Women, Work and Poverty|chapter-url=http://www.ucm.es/cont/descargas/documento6327.pdf|publisher=[[United Nations Development Fund for Women|UNIFEM]]|author2=Vanek, Joann|author3=Lund, Francie|author4=Heintz, James|author5=Jhabvala, Renana|author6=Bonner, Christine|chapter=The Totality of Women's Work|pages=22–35|url-status = dead|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120626004713/http://www.ucm.es/cont/descargas/documento6327.pdf|archive-date=2012-06-26}}</ref> Sabine O'Hara argues that care is the basis for all economic activity and [[market economy|market economies]], concluding that "everything needs care," not only people, but animals and things. She highlights the sustaining nature of care services offered outside the formal economy.<ref>{{cite book|last1=O'Hara|first1=Sabine|editor1-last=Bjørnholt|editor1-first =Margunn|editor1-link=Margunn Bjørnholt|editor2-last=McKay|editor2-first =Ailsa|editor2-link=Ailsa McKay|title=Counting on Marilyn Waring: New Advances in Feminist Economics|year=2014|location=Bradford|publisher=[[Demeter Press]]|pages=37–56|chapter=Everything Needs Care: Toward a Context-Based Economy|isbn=9781927335277|chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Sbh8AwAAQBAJ&pg=PA37}}</ref> [[Riane Eisler]] claims we need the economic system, to give visibility to the essential work of caring for people and caring for nature. Measuring [[GDP]] only includes productive work and leaves out the life sustaining activities of the following three sectors: the household economy, the natural economy and the volunteer community economy. These sectors are where most of the [[care work]] is done. By changing existing [[economic indicator]]s in a way that they would also measure the contributions of the three aforementioned sectors we can get a more accurate reflection of economic reality. She proposes social wealth indicators. According to her these indicators would show the enormous return on investment (ROI) in caring for people and nature. Psychological studies have shown that when people feel good, and they feel good when they feel cared for, they are more productive and more creative (example case study<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Vinarski-Peretz and Carmeli|date=2011|title=Linking Care Felt to Engagement in Innovative Behaviors in the Workplace: The Mediating Role of Psychological Conditions|journal=Psychology of Aesthetics, Creativity, and the Arts|volume=5|issue=1|pages=43–53|via=ResearchGate|doi=10.1037/a0018241}}</ref>). As a result, the care economy has positive [[externalities]] such as increasing the quality of human capital.<ref>{{Cite book|title=The Real Wealth of Nations: Creating a Caring Economics|last=Eisler|first=Riane|publisher=Berrett-Koehler Publishers|year=2008|isbn=978-1576756294}}</ref> Most nations not only fail to support the care work that is still predominantly done by women, but we live in the world with gendered system of values. Everything that is associated with women or femininity is devalued or even marginalised. We need to leave behind the gender double standard that devaluates caring. Only then we can shift from domination to partnership and create a new economic model that Eisler proposes in her book The Real Wealth of Nations: Creating a Caring Economics. Contributions of people and of nature present the real wealth of the society and our [[Economic policy|economic policies]] and practices must support caring for both she claims. Feminist economists have also highlighted power and inequality issues within families and households. For example, [[Randy Albelda]] shows that responsibility for care work influences the time poverty experienced by single mothers in the United States.<ref name="albelda">{{cite journal|last=Albelda|first=Randy|title=Time Binds: US Antipoverty Policies, Poverty, and the Well-Being of Single Mothers|journal=Feminist Economics|date=October 2011|volume=17|issue=4|pages=189–214|doi=10.1080/13545701.2011.602355|s2cid=153867022}}</ref> Similarly, Sarah Gammage examines the effects of unpaid care work performed by women in [[Guatemala]].<ref>{{cite journal|last=Gammage|first=Sarah|title=Time Pressed and Time Poor: Unpaid Household Work in Guatemala|journal=Feminist Economics|date=July 2010|volume=16|issue=3|pages=79–112|doi=10.1080/13545701.2010.498571|s2cid=154932871}}</ref> The work of the Equality Studies Department at [[University College Dublin]] such as that of Sara Cantillon has focused on inequalities of domestic arrangements within even affluent households. While much care work is performed in the home, it may also be done for pay. As such, feminist economics examine its implications, including the increasing involvement of women in paid care work, the potential for exploitation, and effects on the lives of care workers.<ref name="razavi"/> Systemic study of the ways women's work is measured, or not measured at all, have been undertaken by [[Marilyn Waring]] (see ''[[If Women Counted]]'') and others in the 1980s and 1990s. These studies began to justify different means of determining value — some of which influenced the theory of [[social capital]] and [[individual capital]], that emerged in the late 1990s and, along with [[ecological economics]], influenced modern [[human development theory]]. (See also the entry on [[Gender and social capital|Gender and Social Capital]].) ===Unpaid work=== [[Unpaid work]] can include [[domestic work]], [[care work]], subsistence work, unpaid market labor and voluntary work. There is no clear consensus on the definition of these categories. But broadly speaking, these kinds of work can be seen as contributing to the reproduction of society. Domestic work is maintenance of the home, and is usually universally recognizable, e.g. doing the laundry. Care work is looking "after a relative or friend who needs support because of age, physical or learning disability, or illness, including mental illness;" this also includes raising children.<ref name=Carmichael>{{cite journal|last=Carmichael|first=Fiona|author2=Hulme, Claire |author3=Sheppard, Sally |author4= Connell, Gemma |title=Work-Life Imbalance: Informal Care and Paid Employment in the UK|journal=Feminist Economics|date=April 2008|volume=14|issue=2 |pages=3–35 |doi=10.1080/13545700701881005 |s2cid=70765098|url=http://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/3534/}}</ref> Care work also involves "close personal or emotional interaction."<ref name=Folbre>{{cite journal|last=Folbre|first=Nancy|author-link=Nancy Folbre|title=Measuring Care: Gender, Empowerment, and the Care Economy|journal=Journal of Human Development|date=July 2006|volume=7|issue=2 |pages=183–199 |doi=10.1080/14649880600768512 |s2cid=17350027}}</ref> Also included in this category is "self-care," in which leisure time and activities are included. Subsistence work is work done in order to meet basic needs, such as collecting water, but does not have market values assigned to it. Although some of these efforts "are categorized as productive activities according to the latest revision of the international [[United Nations System of National Accounts|System of National Accounts]] (SNA) ... [they] are poorly measured by most surveys."<ref name=Folbre /> Unpaid market work is "the direct contributions of unpaid family members to market work that officially belongs to another member of the household."<ref name=Philipps>{{cite journal|last=Philipps|first=Lisa|title=Silent Partners: The Role of Unpaid Market Labor in Families|journal=Feminist Economics|date=April 1, 2008|volume=14|issue=2|pages=37–57|ssrn=1483263|doi=10.1080/13545700701880981|s2cid=154507941|url=https://digitalcommons.osgoode.yorku.ca/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=2212&context=scholarly_works }}</ref> Voluntary work is usually work done for non-household members, but in return for little to no remuneration. ====System of National Accounts==== Each country measures its economic output according to the System of National Accounts (SNA), sponsored mainly by the [[United Nations]] (UN), but implemented mainly by other organizations such as the [[European Commission]], the [[International Monetary Fund]] (IMF), the [[Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development]] (OECD), and the [[World Bank]]. The SNA recognizes that unpaid work is an area of interest, but "unpaid household services are excluded from [its] production boundary."<ref name=UN>{{cite book|title=System of National Accounts, 2008|year=2009|publisher=United Nations|location=New York|isbn=978-92-1-161522-7|url=http://unstats.un.org/unsd/nationalaccount/docs/SNA2008.pdf}}</ref> Feminist economists have criticized the SNA for this exclusion, because by leaving out unpaid work, basic and necessary labor is ignored. Even accounting measures intended to recognize gender disparities are criticized for ignoring unpaid work. Two such examples are the [[Gender-related Development Index]] (GDI) and the [[Gender Empowerment Measure]] (GEM), neither of which include much unpaid work.<ref name=Beteta>{{cite journal|last=Beteta|first=Hanny Cueva|title=What is missing in measures of Women's Empowerment?|journal=Journal of Human Development|date=July 2006|volume=7|issue=2|pages=221–241 |doi=10.1080/14649880600768553|s2cid=216116889 |url=https://repositorio.unal.edu.co/handle/unal/80807 }}</ref> So feminist economics calls for a more comprehensive index which includes participation in unpaid work. In more recent years there has been increasing attention to this issue, such as recognition of unpaid work within SNA reports and a commitment by the UN to the measurement and valuation of unpaid work, emphasizing care work done by women. This goal was restated at the 1995 UN Fourth World Conference on Women in Beijing.<ref name=Luxton>{{Cite journal | last = Luxton | first = Meg | title = The UN, women, and household labour: Measuring and valuing unpaid work | journal = [[Women's Studies International Forum]] | volume = 20 | issue = 3 | pages = 431–439 | doi = 10.1016/S0277-5395(97)00026-5 | date = May–June 1997 }}</ref> ====Measurement of unpaid work==== The method most widely used to measure unpaid work is gathering information on [[Time-use research|time use]], which has "been implemented by at least 20 developing countries and more are underway" as of 2006.<ref name=Folbre /> Time use measurement involves collecting data on how much time men and women spend on a daily, weekly, or monthly basis on certain activities that fall under the categories of unpaid work. Techniques to gather this data include surveys, in-depth interviews, diaries, and participant observation.<ref name=Luxton /><ref name=Mullan>{{cite journal|last=Mullan|first=Killian|title=Valuing Parental Childcare in the United Kingdom|journal=Feminist Economics|date=July 2010|volume=16|issue=3|pages=113–139|doi=10.1080/13545701.2010.504014|s2cid=154612725}}</ref> Proponents of time use diaries believe that this method "generate[s] more detailed information and tend[s] to capture greater variation than predetermined questions."<ref name=Luxton /> However, others argue that participant observation, "where the researcher spends lengthy periods of time in households helping out and observing the labor process," generates more accurate information because the researcher can ascertain whether or not those studied are accurately reporting what activities they perform.<ref name=Luxton /> =====Accuracy===== The first problem of measuring unpaid work is the issue of collecting accurate information. This is always a concern in research studies, but is particularly difficult when evaluating unpaid work. "Time-use surveys may reveal relatively little time devoted to unpaid direct care activities [because] the demands of subsistence production in those countries are great," and may not take into account multitasking — for example, a mother may collect wood fuel while a child is in the same location, so the child is in her care while she is performing other work.<ref name=Folbre /> Usually such indirect care should be included, as it is in many time use studies. But it is not always, and as a result some studies may undervalue the amount of certain types of unpaid work. Participant observation has been criticized for being "so time-consuming that it can only focus on small numbers of households," and thus limited in the amount of information it can be used to gather.<ref name=Luxton /> All data gathering involves difficulties with the potential inaccuracy of research subjects' reports. For instance, when "people doing domestic labor have no reason to pay close attention to the amount of time tasks take ... they [may] often underestimate time spent in familiar activities."<ref name=Luxton /> Measuring time can also be problematic because "the slowest and most inefficient workers [appear to carry] the greatest workload."<ref name=Luxton /> Time use in assessing childcare is criticized as "easily obscur[ing] gender differences in workload. Men and women may both put in the same amount of time being responsible for children but as participant observation studies have shown, many men are more likely to 'babysit' their children while doing something for themselves, such as watching TV. Men's standards of care may be limited to ensuring the children are not hurt. Dirty diapers may be ignored or deliberately left until the mother returns."<ref name=Luxton /> A paradoxical aspect of this problem is that those most burdened may not be able to participate in the studies: "It is usually those women with the heaviest work loads who choose not to participate in these studies."<ref name=Luxton /> In general, measurement of time causes "some of the most demanding aspects of unpaid work [to be unexplored] and the premise that time is an appropriate tool for measuring women's unpaid work goes unchallenged."<ref name=Luxton /> Surveys have also been criticized for lacking "depth and complexity" as questions cannot be specifically tailored to particular circumstances.<ref name=Luxton /> =====Comparability===== A second problem is the difficulty of comparisons across cultures. "Comparisons across countries are currently hampered by differences in activity classification and nomenclature."<ref name=Folbre /> In-depth surveys may be the only way to get necessary information desired, but they make it difficult to perform cross-cultural comparisons.<ref name=Luxton /> The lack of adequate universal terminology in discussing unpaid work is an example. "Despite increasing recognition that domestic labor is work, existing vocabularies do not easily convey the new appreciations. People still tend to talk about work and home as if they were separate spheres. 'Working mothers' are usually assumed to be in the paid labor force, despite feminist assertions that 'every mother is a working mother.' There are no readily accepted terms to express different work activities or job titles. Housewife, home manager, homemaker are all problematic and none of them conveys the sense of a woman who juggles both domestic labor and paid employment."<ref name=Luxton /> =====Complexity===== A third problem is the complexity of domestic labor and the issues of separating unpaid work categories. Time use studies now take multitasking issues into account, separating primary and secondary activities. However, not all studies do this, and even those that do may not take into account "the fact that frequently several tasks are done simultaneously, that tasks overlap, and that the boundaries between work and relationships are often unclear. How does a woman determine her primary activity when she is preparing dinner while putting the laundry away, making coffee for her spouse, having coffee and chatting with him, and attending to the children?"<ref name=Luxton /> Some activities may not even be considered work, such as playing with a child (this has been categorized as developmental care work) and so may not be included in a study's responses.<ref name=Luxton /> As mentioned above, child supervision (indirect care work) may not be construed as an activity at all, which "suggests that activity-based surveys should be supplemented by more stylized questions regarding care responsibilities" as otherwise such activities can be undercounted.<ref name=Folbre /> In the past, time use studies tended to measure only primary activities, and "respondents doing two or more things at once were asked to indicate which was the more important." This has been changing in more recent years.<ref name=Luxton /> ====Valuation of time==== Feminist economists point out three main ways of determining the value of unpaid work: the [[opportunity cost]] method, [[replacement cost]] method, and input-output cost method. The opportunity cost method "uses the wage a person would earn in the market" to see how much value their labor-time has.<ref name=Mullan /> This method extrapolates from the opportunity cost idea in mainstream economics. The second method of valuation uses replacement costs. In simple terms, this is done by measuring the amount of money a third-party would make for doing the same work if it was part of the market. In other words, the value of a person cleaning the house in an hour is the same as the hourly wage for a maid. Within this method there are two approaches: the first is a generalist replacement cost method, which examines if "it would be possible, for example, to take the wage of a general domestic worker who could perform a variety of tasks including childcare".<ref name=Mullan /> The second approach is the specialist replacement cost method, which aims to "distinguish between the different household tasks and choose replacements accordingly".<ref name=Mullan /> The third method is the input-output cost method. This looks at both the costs of inputs and includes any value added by the household. "For instance, the value of time devoted to cooking a meal can be determined by asking what it could cost to purchase a similar meal (the output) in the market, then subtracting the cost of the capital goods, utilities and raw materials devoted to that meal. This remainder represents the value of the other factors of production, primarily labor."<ref name=Folbre /> These types of models try to value household output by determining monetary values for the inputs — in the dinner example, the ingredients and production of the meal — and compares those with market equivalents.<ref name=Luxton /> =====Difficulty establishing monetary levels===== One criticism of time valuation concerns the choice of monetary levels. How should unpaid work be valued when more than one activity is being performed or more than one output is produced? Another issue concerns differences in quality between market and household products. Some feminist economists take issue with using the market system to determine values for a variety of reasons: it may lead to the conclusion that the market provides perfect substitutes for non-market work;<ref name=Folbre /> the wage produced in the market for services may not accurately reflect the actual opportunity cost of time spent in household production;<ref name=Mullan /> and the wages used in valuation methods come from industries where wages are already depressed because of gender inequalities, and so will not accurately value unpaid work.<ref name=Mullan /> A related argument is that the market "accepts existing sex/gender divisions of labor and pay inequalities as normal and unproblematic. With this basic assumption underlying their calculations, the valuations produced serve to reinforce gender inequalities rather than challenge women's subordination."<ref name=Luxton /> =====Criticisms of opportunity cost===== Criticisms are leveled against each method of valuation. The opportunity cost method "depends on the lost earnings of the worker so that a toilet cleaned by a lawyer has much greater value than one cleaned by a janitor", which means that the value varies too drastically.<ref name=Luxton /> There are also issues with the uniformity of this method not just across multiple individuals, but also for a single person: it "may not be uniform across the entire day or across days of the week."<ref name=Mullan /> There is also the issue of whether any enjoyment of the activity should be deducted from the opportunity cost estimate.<ref name=Mullan /> =====Difficulties with replacement cost===== The replacement cost method also has its critics. What types of jobs should be used as substitutes? For example, should childcare activities "be calculated using the wages of daycare workers or child psychiatrists?"<ref name=Mullan /> This relates to the problem of depressed wages in female-dominated industries, and whether using such jobs as an equivalent leads to the undervaluing of unpaid work. Some have argued that education levels ought to be comparable, for example, "the value of time that a college-educated parent spends reading aloud to a child should be ascertained by asking how much it would cost to hire a college-educated worker to do the same, not by an average housekeeper's wage."<ref name=Folbre /> =====Difficulties with input-output methods===== Critiques against the input-output methods include the difficulty of identifying and measuring household outputs, and the issues of variation of households and these effects.<ref name=Mullan /> ====Findings and economic effects of unpaid work==== In 2011, a wide-ranging study was conducted to determine the amount of unpaid household work engaged in by residents of different countries. This study, incorporating the results of time-use surveys from 26 [[Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development|OECD]] countries, found that, in each country, the average hours spent per day on unpaid household work was between about 2 to 4 hours per day.<ref>{{cite web|title=Incorporating Estimates of Household Production of Non-Market Services Into International Comparisons of Material Well-Being|url=http://www.oecd.org/officialdocuments/publicdisplaydocumentpdf/?cote=std/doc(2011)7&doclanguage=en}}</ref> As domestic work is widely seen as "women's work", the majority of it is performed by women, even for women who also participate in the labor force. One study found that, when adding the time spent on unpaid household work to the time spent engaging in paid work, married mothers accumulate 84 hours of work per week, compared to 79 hours per week for unmarried mothers, and 72 hours per week for all fathers, whether married or not.<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Sirianni|first1=Carmen|last2=Negrey|first2=Cynthia|title=Working Time as Gendered Time|journal=Feminist Economics|volume=6|pages=59–76|doi=10.1080/135457000337679|date=1 January 2000|s2cid=154879132|url=http://elartu.tntu.edu.ua/handle/lib/39819 }}</ref> Efforts to calculate the true economic value of unpaid work, which is not included in measures such as [[gross domestic product]], have shown that this value is enormous. In the United States, it has been estimated to be between 20 and 50%, meaning that the true value of unpaid work is trillions of dollars per year. For other countries, the percentage of GDP may be even higher, such as the United Kingdom, where is may be as high as 70%.<ref>{{cite web|title=Incorporating Estimates of Household Production of Non-Market Services into International Comparisons of Material Well-Being|url=http://www.oecd.org/officialdocuments/publicdisplaydocumentpdf/?cote=std/doc(2011)7&doclanguage=en}}</ref> Because this unpaid work is largely done by women and is unreported in economic indicators, it results in these contributions by women being devalued in a society. ===The formal economy=== Research into the causes and consequences of [[occupational segregation]], the [[gender pay gap]], and the "[[glass ceiling]]" have been a significant part of feminist economics. While conventional neoclassical economic theories of the 1960s and 1970s explained these as the result of free choices made by women and men who simply had different abilities or preferences, feminist economists pointed out the important roles played by [[stereotyping]], [[sexism]], [[patriarchal]] beliefs and institutions, [[sexual harassment]], and [[discrimination]].<ref>e.g., {{cite journal|last=Bergmann|first=Barbara R.|title=Occupational Segregation, Wages and Profits When Employers Discriminate by Race or Sex|journal=Eastern Economic Journal|date=April 1974|volume=1|issue=2|pages=103–110|jstor=40315472}} See also [[male-female income disparity in the United States]].</ref> The rationales for, and the effects of, [[anti-discrimination law]]s adopted in many industrial countries beginning in the 1970s, has also been studied.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Beller|first=Andrea H.|title=Occupational Segregation by Sex: Determinants and Changes|journal=The Journal of Human Resources|date=Summer 1982|volume=17|issue=3|pages=371–392|jstor=145586|doi=10.2307/145586}}; Bergmann, Barbara. ''In Defense of Affirmative Action'', New York: Basic Books, 1996.</ref> Women moved in large numbers into previous male bastions — especially professions like medicine and law — during the last decades of the 20th century. The [[gender pay gap]] remains and is shrinking more slowly. Feminist economists such as Marilyn Power, Ellen Mutari and Deborah M. Figart have examined the gender pay gap and found that wage setting procedures are not primarily driven by market forces, but instead by the power of actors, cultural understandings of the value of work and what constitutes a proper living, and social gender norms.<ref>{{cite book|title=Toward a Feminist Philosophy of Economics|volume=20031146|year=2003|publisher=Routledge|location=London [u.a.]|isbn=978-0-415-28387-8|pages=70–86|chapter=Beyond Markets: Wage Setting and the Methodology of Feminist Political Economy|author=Power, Marilyn|author2=Mutari, Ellen|author3=Figart, Deborah M.|doi=10.4324/9780203422694 |series=Economics as Social Theory}}</ref> Consequently, they assert that economic models must take these typically exogenous variables into account. While overt employment discrimination by sex remains a concern of feminist economists, in recent years more attention has been paid to discrimination against [[caregivers]]—those women, and some men, who give hands-on care to children or sick or elderly friends or relatives. Because many business and government policies were designed to accommodate the "ideal worker" (that is, the traditional male worker who had no such responsibilities) rather than caregiver-workers, inefficient and inequitable treatment has resulted.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Waldfogel|first=Jane|title=The Effect of Children on Women's Wages|journal=American Sociological Review|date=April 1997|volume=62|issue=2|pages=209–217|jstor=2657300|doi=10.2307/2657300}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal | doi=10.1080/1354570042000217694| title=The dilemmas of lone motherhood: Key issues for feminist economics| journal=Feminist Economics| volume=10| issue=2| pages=1–7| year=2004| last1=Albelda| first1=Randy| last2=Himmelweit| first2=Susan| last3=Humphries| first3=Jane| s2cid=154585874}}</ref><ref>{{cite book | last = Williams | first = Joan | author-link = Joan C Williams | title = Unbending gender: why family and work conflict and what to do about it | publisher = Oxford University Press | location = Oxford New York | year = 2000 | isbn = 9780195147148 }}</ref> ===Globalization=== Feminist economists' work on [[globalization]] is diverse and multifaceted. But much of it is tied together through detailed and nuanced studies of the ways in which globalization affects women in particular and how these effects relate to [[social justice|socially just]] outcomes. Often country [[case studies]] are used for these data.<ref name="berik"/> Some feminist economists focus on policies involving the development of globalization. For example, [[Lourdes Benería]] argues that [[economic development]] in the [[Global South]] depends in large part on improved reproductive rights, gender equitable laws on ownership and inheritance, and policies that are sensitive to the proportion of women in the [[informal economy]].<ref name=gdgeaipm>{{cite book | last = Benería | first = Lourdes | author-link=Lourdes Benería | title = Gender, development, and globalization: economics as if all people mattered | publisher = Routledge | location = New York | year = 2003 | isbn = 9780415927079 }} ([http://appweb.cortland.edu/ojs/index.php/Wagadu/article/viewFile/383/729 Book review] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20140119062111/http://appweb.cortland.edu/ojs/index.php/Wagadu/article/viewFile/383/729 |date=2014-01-19 }})</ref> Additionally, Nalia Kabeer discusses the impacts of a [[social clause]] that would enforce global labor standards through international trade agreements, drawing on fieldwork from [[Bangladesh]].<ref name="kabeer">{{cite journal|last=Kabeer|first=Naila|title=Globalization, labor standards, and women's rights: dilemmas of collective (in)action in an interdependent world|journal=Feminist Economics|date=March 2004|volume=10|issue=1|pages=3–35|doi=10.1080/1354570042000198227|s2cid=17533079}}</ref> She argues that although these jobs may appear exploitative, for many workers in those areas they present opportunities and ways to avoid more exploitative situations in the [[informal economy]]. Alternatively, [[Suzanne Bergeron]], for example, raises examples of studies that illustrate the multifaceted effects of globalization on women, including Kumudhini Rosa's study of [[Sri Lanka]]n, [[Malaysia]]n, and [[Philippines|Philippine]], workers in [[free trade zone]]s as an example of local resistance to globalization.<ref name="bergeron">{{cite journal|last=Bergeron|first=Suzanne|title=Political Economy Discourses of Globalization and Feminist Politics|journal=Signs|date=Summer 2001|volume=26|issue=4|pages=983–1006|jstor=3175354|doi=10.1086/495645|s2cid=154014443}}</ref> Women there use their wages to create women's centers aimed at providing legal and medical services, libraries and [[cooperative housing]], to local community members. Such efforts, Bergeron highlights, allow women the chance to take control of economic conditions, increase their sense of individualism, and alter the pace and direction of globalization itself. In other cases, feminist economists work on removing gender biases from the theoretical bases of globalization itself. [[Suzanne Bergeron]], for example, focuses on the typical theories of globalization as the "rapid integration of the world into one economic space" through the flow of [[good (economics)|good]]s, [[Financial capital|capital]], and [[money]], in order to show how they exclude some women and the disadvantaged.<ref name="bergeron"/> She argues that traditional understandings of globalization over-emphasize the power of global [[capital flows]], the uniformity of globalization experiences across all populations, and technical and abstract economic processes, and therefore depict the [[political economy]] of globalization inappropriately. She highlights the alternative views of globalization created by feminists. First, she describes how feminists may de-emphasize the idea of the market as "a natural and unstoppable force," instead depicting the process of globalization as alterable and movable by individual economic actors including women. She also explains that the concept of globalization itself is gender biased, because its depiction as "dominant, unified, [and] intentional" is inherently masculinized and misleading. She suggests that feminists critique such narratives by showing how a "global economy" is highly complex, de-centered and unclear. ===Degrowth and Ecological economics=== Feminist and ecological economics so far have not engaged with one another much.<ref>Corinna Dengler and Birte Strunk (2017) "The Monetized Economy Versus Care and the Environment: Degrowth Perspectives On Reconciling an Antagonism, Feminist Economics" ''Feminist Economics'' '''3'''(24):160-183. [https://doi.org/10.1080/13545701.2017.1383620 doi:10.1080/13545701.2017.1383620]</ref> argue for the [[degrowth]] approach as a useful critique of the devaluation of care and nature by the "growth-based capitalist economic paradigm". They argue that the growth paradigm perpetuates existing gender and environmental injustices and seek to mitigate it with a degrowth work-sharing proposal. Scholars in the paradigm of [[degrowth]] point out that the contemporary economic imaginary considers time as a scarce resource to be allocated efficiently, while in the domestic and care sector time use depends on the rhythm of life. (D’Alisa et al. 2014: Degrowth. A Vocabulary for a New Era, New York, NY: Routledge.) Joan Tronto (1993: Moral Boundaries: A Political Argument for an Ethic of Care, New York, NY: Routledge.) divides the care process in four phases: caring about, taking care of, care-giving and care-receiving. These acquire different meanings when used describing the actions of males and females. Degrowth proposes to put care at the center of society, thus calling for a radical rethinking of human relations. It should be pointed out that degrowth is a concept that originated in the global north and is mainly directed towards a reduction of the economic (and therefore material) throughput of affluent societies. Environmental injustices linked to gender injustices are embedded in "Green Growth" due to its inability to dematerialize production processes, and these injustices are perpetuated through the Green Growth narrative and through its consequences. Ecological processes as well as caring activities are similarly, systematically devalued by the dominating industrial and economic paradigms. This can be explained by the arbitrary boundary between the monetized and the maintaining that remains largely unchallenged. Degrowth presents itself as an alternative to this dualistic view. If designed in a gender-sensitive way that recenters society around care could have the potential to alleviate environmental injustices while promoting greater gender equality. ==Methodology== ===Interdisciplinary data collection=== Many feminist economists challenge the perception that only "objective" (often presumed to be [[quantitative research|quantitative]]) data are valid.<ref name="nelson1"/> Instead, they say economists should enrich their analysis by using data sets generated from other disciplines or through increased use of qualitative methods.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Berik|first=Günseli|title=The Need for Crossing the Method Boundaries in Economics Research|journal=Feminist Economics|date=January 1997|volume=3|issue=2|pages=121–125|doi=10.1080/135457097338735}}</ref> Additionally, many feminist economists propose utilizing non-traditional data collection strategies such as "utilizing growth accounting frameworks, conducting [[empirical]] tests of economic theories, developing country [[case studies]], and pursuing research at the conceptual and empirical levels."<ref name="berik"/> Interdisciplinary data collection looks at systems from a specific moral position and viewpoint instead of attempting the perspective of a neutral observer. The intention is not to create a more "subjective" methodology, but to counter biases in existing methodologies, by recognizing that all explanations for world phenomena arise from socially-influenced viewpoints. Feminist economists say too many theories claim to present universal principles but actually present a masculine viewpoint in the guise of a "[[view from nowhere]]", so more varied sources of data collection are needed to mediate those issues.<ref>{{cite book | last = Nelson | first = Julie | author-link = Julie A. Nelson | title = Feminism, objectivity and economics | publisher = Routledge | location = London New York | year = 1996 | isbn = 9780203435915 }}</ref> ===Ethical judgment=== Feminist economists depart from traditional economics in that they say "[[ethics|ethical]] judgments are a valid, inescapable, and in fact desirable part of economic analysis."<ref name="Power, Marilyn 2011"/> For example, Lourdes Beneria argues that judgments about policies leading to greater well-being should be central to economic analysis.<ref name=gdgeaipm /> Similarly, [[Shahra Razavi]] says better understanding of care work "would allow us to shift our priorities from 'making money' or 'making stuff' to 'making livable lives' and 'enriching networks of care and relationship'" which should be central to economics.<ref name="razavi"/> ===Country case studies=== Often feminist economists use country-level or smaller [[case studies]] focused on [[developing country|developing]] and often understudied countries or populations.<ref name="berik"/> For example, Michael Kevane and Leslie C. Gray examine how gendered [[social norms]] are central to understanding agricultural activities in [[Burkina Faso]].<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Kevane |first1=Michael| last2=Gray| first2 =Leslie C.| title=A Woman's Field Is Made At Night: Gendered Land Rights And Norms In Burkina Faso|journal=Feminist Economics|date=January 1999|volume=5|issue=3|pages=1–26|doi=10.1080/135457099337789| url=https://ideas.repec.org/a/taf/femeco/v5y1999i3p1-26.html|citeseerx=10.1.1.194.4747|s2cid=17311467 }}</ref> Cristina Carrasco and Arantxa Rodriquez examine the care economy in [[Spain]] to suggest that women's entrance into the labor market requires more equitable caregiving responsibilities.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Carrasco|first=Cristina|author2=RodrÍguez, Arantxa|title=Women, Families, and Work in Spain: Structural Changes and New Demands|journal=Feminist Economics|date=January 2000|volume=6|issue=1|pages=45–57|doi=10.1080/135457000337660|s2cid=154618578|url=https://ideas.repec.org/a/taf/femeco/v6y2000i1p45-57.html}}</ref> Such studies show the importance of local social norms, government policies and cultural situations. Feminist economists see such variation as a crucial factor to be included in economics. ===Alternative measures of success=== Feminist economists call for a shift in how economic success is measured. These changes include an increased focus on a policy's ability to bring society toward social justice and improve people's lives, through specific goals including distributive fairness, equity, the universal provisioning of needs, elimination of [[poverty]], freedom from [[discrimination]] and the protection of human capabilities.<ref name="berik"/><ref name="elsoncagatay">{{cite journal|last1=Elson|first1=Diane|author2=Cagatay, Nilufer|author-link1=Diane Elson|title=The Social Content of Macroeconomic Policies|journal=World Development|date=July 2000|volume=28|issue=7|pages=1347–1364|doi=10.1016/S0305-750X(00)00021-8|url=http://csde.washington.edu/~scurran/files/readings/May19/Elson.%20Social%20Content%20of%20Macroeconomic%20Policies.pdf|access-date=2012-09-26|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100625045358/http://csde.washington.edu/~scurran/files/readings/May19/Elson.%20Social%20Content%20of%20Macroeconomic%20Policies.pdf|archive-date=2010-06-25|url-status = dead}}</ref> ==== Human Development Index (HDI) ==== [[File:2011 UN Human Development Report Quartiles.svg|400px|thumb|right|World map by quartiles of Human Development Index in 2011 {| border="0" cellspacing="0" cellpadding="0" style="width:100%;" |- | {{legend|#003399|Very High (developed country)}} || {{legend|#E6EDFF|Low (developing country)}} |- | {{legend|#3072D9|High (developing country)}} || {{legend|#858585|Data unavailable}} |- | {{legend|#A8C3FF|Medium (developing country)}} || |}]] {{main|Human Development Index}} Feminist economists often support use of the [[Human Development Index]] as a composite statistic in order to assess countries by their overall level of [[human development (humanity)|human development]], as opposed to other measures. The HDI takes into account a broad array of measures beyond monetary considerations including [[life expectancy]], literacy, education, and standards of living for all countries worldwide.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Fukuda-Parr|first=Sakiko|author-link=Sakiko Fukuda-Parr|title=The Human Development Paradigm: Operationalizing Sen's Ideas on Capabilities|journal=Feminist Economics|date=January 2003|volume=9|issue=2–3|pages=301–317|doi=10.1080/1354570022000077980|url=http://econpapers.repec.org/article/taffemeco/v_3a9_3ay_3a2003_3ai_3a2-3_3ap_3a301-317.htm|citeseerx=10.1.1.456.4127|s2cid=18178004}}</ref> ====Gender-related Development Index (GDI)==== {{main|Gender-related Development Index}} The '''Gender-related Development Index''' (GDI) was introduced in 1995 in the [[Human Development Report]] written by the [[United Nations Development Program]] in order to add a gender-sensitive dimension to the Human Development Index. The GDI takes into account not only the average or general level of well-being and wealth within a given country, but also how this wealth and well-being is distributed between different groups within society, especially between genders.<ref name="Gender">{{cite journal|last=Klasen|first=Stephan|title=UNDP's Gender-related Measures: Some Conceptual Problems and Possible Solutions|journal=Journal of Human Development|date=July 2006|volume=7|issue=2|pages=243–274|doi=10.1080/14649880600768595|s2cid=15421076}} Available from: EconLit with Full Text, Ipswich, MA. Accessed September 26, 2011.</ref> However, feminist economists do not universally agree on the use of the GDI and some offer improvements to it.<ref>{{Cite journal | last1= Klasen |first1= Stephan | last2 = Schüler | first2 = Dana | title = Reforming the gender-related development index and the gender empowerment measure: implementing some specific proposals | journal = Feminist Economics| volume = 17 | issue = 1 | pages = 1–30 | doi = 10.1080/13545701.2010.541860 | date = 2011 |s2cid= 154373171 }}</ref> ====Social Institutions and Gender Index (SIGI)==== The Social Institutions and Gender Index (SIGI) is a recently developed measure of [[gender inequality]] calculated by analyzing social institutions, societal practices, and legal norms and how these factors largely frame gender norms within a society. By combining these sources of inequality, SIGI is able to penalize high levels of inequality in each of the applicable dimensions, allowing for only partial compensation by the gaps between the remaining dimensions and the highly inequitable one. Through its analysis of the institutional sources of gender inequality in over 100 countries, SIGI has been proven to add new insights into outcomes for women, even when other factors such as religion and region of the world are controlled for.<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Branisa|first1=Boris|last2=Klasen|first2=Stephan|last3=Ziegler|first3=Maria|last4=Drechsler|first4=Denis|last5=Jütting|first5=Johannes|title=The Institutional Basis of Gender Inequality: The Social Institutions and Gender Index (SIGI)|journal=Feminist Economics|volume=20|issue=2|pages=29–64|doi=10.1080/13545701.2013.850523|year=2014|s2cid=154769451|url=https://zenodo.org/record/897865}}<!--https://zenodo.org/record/897865--></ref> SIGI rankings largely mirror those of the HDI, with countries such as Portugal and Argentina leading the pack, while countries like Afghanistan and Sudan are significantly behind. ==Organizations== Feminist economics continues to become more widely recognized and reputed as evidenced by the numerous organizations dedicated to it or widely influenced by its principles. ===International Association for Feminist Economics=== {{main|International Association for Feminist Economics}} Formed in 1992, the [[International Association for Feminist Economics|International Association for Feminist Economics (IAFFE)]], is independent of the [[American Economic Association]] (AEA) and seeks to challenge the masculine biases in neoclassical economics.<ref name="beyond2">{{cite book|last1=Ferber|first1=Marianne A.|author-link1=Marianne Ferber|title=Feminist Economics Today: Beyond Economic Man|year=2003|publisher=Univ. of Chicago Press |location= Chicago |isbn= 978-0-226-24206-4 |page=7 |chapter-url= https://books.google.com/books?id=ziv8m0ihvYAC&q=Beyond%20Economic%20Man%3A%20Ten%20Years%20Later&pg=PT14|author2=Nelson, Julie A.|author2-link=Julie A. Nelson|chapter=Beyond Economic Man, Ten Years Later|quote= In 1990 a few dissidents in the United States got together and discussed their ideas for starting an organization of their own. Taking advantage of the large attendance at a panel organized by [[Diana Strassman]] entitled "Can Feminism Find a Home in Economics?" Jean Shackelford and April Aerni invited members of the audience to sign up to start a new network with an explicitly feminist slant. Two years later, this network was transformed into the International Association for Feminist Economics (IAFFE).}}</ref> While the majority of members are economists, it is open "not only to female and male economists but to academics from other fields, as well as activists who are not academics" and currently has over 600 members in 64 countries.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.iaffe.org/pages/about-iaffe/history/ |title=History |publisher=International Association for Feminist Economics |access-date=2012-06-20 |archive-date=2019-05-10 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190510115457/http://www.iaffe.org/pages/about-iaffe/history/ |url-status=dead }}</ref> Although its founding members were mostly based in the US, a majority of IAFFE's current members are based outside of the US. In 1997, IAFFE gained [[Non-Governmental Organization]] status in the [[United Nations]]. ===''Feminist Economics'' journal=== {{main|Feminist Economics (journal)|}} ''Feminist Economics'', edited by [[Diana Strassmann]] of [[Rice University]] and Günseli Berik of the [[University of Utah]], is a peer-reviewed journal established to provide an open forum for dialogue and debate about feminist economic perspectives. The journal endorses a normative agenda to promote policies that will better the lives of the world's people, both women and men. In 1997, the journal was awarded the [[The Council of Editors of Learned Journals|Council of Editors and Learned Journals (CELJ)]] Award as Best New Journal.<ref name=CELJ>{{cite web|title=Best New Journal - 1997 Winner|url=http://www.celj.org/best_new_journal|publisher=[[The Council of Editors of Learned Journals|The Council of Editors and Learned Journals (CELJ)]]|access-date=2 May 2014|url-status = dead|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20111102232157/http://www.celj.org/best_new_journal|archive-date=2 November 2011}}</ref> The 2007 [[Social Sciences Citation Index|ISI Social Science Citation Index]] ranked the journal ''Feminist Economics'' 20th out of 175 among economics journals and 2nd out of 27 among Women's Studies journals.<ref name=Rice>{{cite web|last=B.J.|first=Almond|title=Feminist Economics rises in journal rankings|url=http://news.rice.edu/2007/02/01/feminist-economics-rises-in-journal-rankings/|publisher=Rice University - News and Media|access-date=2 May 2014|date=1 February 2007|archive-date=16 February 2019|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190216045009/http://news.rice.edu/2007/02/01/feminist-economics-rises-in-journal-rankings/|url-status=dead}}</ref> == Graduate programs == A small, but growing number of graduate programs around the world offer courses and concentrations in feminist economics. (Unless otherwise noted below, these offerings are in departments of economics.) {{columns-list|colwidth=30em| *[[American University]] *[[School of Public Policy and Administration at Carleton University]] *[[Colorado State University]] *[[Institute of Social Studies]] *Gender Institute of the [[London School of Economics]] *[[Makerere University]] *[[University of Massachusetts Amherst]] *The Masters in Applied Economics and Public Policy programs at the [[University of Massachusetts Boston]] *[[University of Nebraska–Lincoln]] *[[The New School for Social Research]] *[[University of Reading]] *[[Roosevelt University]] *Department of Women's and Gender Studies at [[Rutgers University]] *Discipline of Political Economy at the [[University of Sydney]] *[[University of Utah]] *[[York University (Toronto)]] *[[Wright State University]] }} ==See also== {{columns-list|colwidth=22em| *[[Family economics]] *[[Critique of political economy]] *[[:Category:Feminism and society|Feminism and society]] *''[[Feminist Economics (journal)|Feminist Economics]]'' (journal) *[[Gender equality]], or gender equity *[[Gender mainstreaming]] *[[Intra-household bargaining]] *[[Material feminism]] *[[Time use]] *[[List of feminist economists]] *[[Who Cooked Adam Smith's Dinner?]] }} ==References== {{reflist|colwidth=30em}} ==Further reading== ; Books *{{cite book|last=Agarwal|first=Bina|author-link=Bina Agarwal|title=A Field of One's Own: Gender and Land Rights in South Asia|year=1994|publisher=Cambridge University Press|isbn=978-0-521-42926-9}} *{{cite book|last=Barker|first=Drucilla K.|title=Liberating Economics: Feminist Perspectives on Families, Work, and Globalization|year=2004|publisher=Univ. of Michigan Press|location=Ann Arbor, Mich.|isbn=978-0-472-06843-2|author2=Feiner, Susan F.}} * {{cite book | last1 = Kuiper | first1 = Edith | last2 = Barker | first2 = Drucilla K. |author-link1= Edith Kuiper | title = Toward a feminist philosophy of economics | publisher = Routledge | location = London New York | year = 2003 | isbn = 9780415283885 }} * {{cite book | last = Benería | first = Lourdes|author-link=Lourdes Benería | title = Gender, development, and globalization: economics as if all people mattered | publisher = Routledge | location = New York | year = 2003 | isbn = 9780415927079 }} *{{cite book|editor1-last=Bjørnholt|editor1-first =Margunn|editor1-link=Margunn Bjørnholt|editor2-last=McKay|editor2-first =Ailsa|editor2-link=Ailsa McKay|title=Counting on Marilyn Waring: New Advances in Feminist Economics|year=2014|publisher=Demeter Press|isbn=9781927335277|title-link =If Women Counted#Counting on Marilyn Waring: New Advances in Feminist Economics}} With a foreword by [[Julie A. Nelson]]. * {{cite book |last1=Esquivel |first1=Valeria |title=Companion to Feminist Studies |date=2020 |publisher=[[John Wiley & Sons]] |isbn=978-1-119-31496-7 |pages=265–279 |url=https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/abs/10.1002/9781119314967.ch15 |language=en |chapter=Feminist Economics |doi=10.1002/9781119314967.ch15}} *{{cite book|editor1-last=Ferber|editor1-first=Marianne A.|editor1-link=Marianne Ferber|editor2-last=Nelson|editor2-first =Julie A.|editor2-link=Julie A. Nelson|title=Beyond Economic Man: Feminist Theory and Economics|year=1993|publisher=Univ. of Chicago Press|location=Chicago [u.a.]|isbn=978-0-226-24201-9}} *{{cite book|last=Jacobsen|first=Joyce P.|title=The Economics of Gender|year=2007|publisher=Blackwell|location=Malden, Massachusetts|isbn=978-1-4051-6182-4}} *{{cite book|last=Nelson|first=Julie A.|author-link=Julie A. Nelson|title=Feminism, Objectivity and Economics|year=1996|publisher=Routledge|location=New York|isbn=978-0-415-13337-1}} *{{cite book|editor-last1=Peterson|editor-first1=Janice|editor-last2=Lewis|editor-first2=Margaret|title=The Elgar Companion to Feminist Economics|year=1999|publisher=Edward Elgar|location=Cheltenham|isbn=978-1-85898-453-7}} *{{cite book|last=Sen|first=Amartya|author-link=Amartya Sen|title=Development as Freedom|year=1999|publisher=Oxford Univ. Press|isbn=978-0-19-289330-7|url-access=registration|url=https://archive.org/details/developmentasfre00sena}} *{{cite book|last=Waring|first=Marilyn |author-link=Marilyn Waring|title=If Women Counted: A New Feminist Economics|year=1989|publisher=Macmillan|location=London|isbn=978-0-333-49262-8|title-link=If Women Counted }} ; Journal articles *{{cite journal|last=Carrasco|first=Cristina|author2=Domínguez, Màrius|title=Family Strategies for Meeting Care and Domestic Work Needs: Evidence From Spain|journal=[[Feminist Economics (journal)|Feminist Economics]]|date=October 2011|volume=17|issue=4|pages=159–188|doi=10.1080/13545701.2011.614625|s2cid=153666691}} *{{cite journal|last=Jenkins|first=Katy|title="We have a lot of goodwill, but we still need to eat…": Valuing Women's Long Term Voluntarism in Community Development in Lima|journal=[[Voluntas (journal)|VOLUNTAS: International Journal of Voluntary and Nonprofit Organizations]]|year=2009|volume=20|issue=1|pages=15–34|doi=10.1007/s11266-008-9075-7|s2cid=153751895}} *{{cite journal|last=Power|first=Marilyn|title=Social Provisioning as a Starting Point for Feminist Economics|journal=[[Feminist Economics (journal)|Feminist Economics]]|date=November 2004|volume=10|issue=3|pages=3–19|doi=10.1080/1354570042000267608|s2cid=145130126}} *{{cite journal|last=Schüler|first=Dana|title=The Uses and Misuses of the Gender-related Development Index and Gender Empowerment Measure: A Review of the Literature|journal=Journal of Human Development|date=July 2006|volume=7|issue=2|pages=161–181|doi=10.1080/14649880600768496|s2cid=347402}} *{{cite news|last=Staff writer|title=A proper reckoning: feminist economics deserves recognition as a distinct branch of the discipline|url=https://www.economist.com/news/finance-and-economics/21694529-feminist-economics-deserves-recognition-distinct-branch-discipline?fsrc=scn%2Ftw_ec%2Fa_proper_reckoning|newspaper=[[The Economist]]|date=12 March 2016}} *{{cite journal|last=Warren|first=Tracey|author2=Pascall, Gillian |author3=Fox, Elizabeth |title=Gender Equality in Time: Low-Paid Mothers' Paid and Unpaid Work in the UK|journal=[[Feminist Economics (journal)|Feminist Economics]]|date=July 2010|volume=16|issue=3|pages=193–219|doi=10.1080/13545701.2010.499997|s2cid=153425125}} ==External links== {{Commons category}} *[http://www.iaffe.org/ International Association for Feminist Economics (IAFFE)] * ''[http://www.feministeconomics.org/ Feminist Economics]'' (peer-reviewed journal) {{Feminist theory}} {{Aspects of capitalism}} {{Critique of political economy}} {{Globalization}} [[Category:Critique of political economy]] [[Category:Feminist economics| ]] [[Category:Feminism and education]] [[Category:Feminism and social class]] [[Category:Schools of economic thought]]
Summary:
Please note that all contributions to Niidae Wiki may be edited, altered, or removed by other contributors. If you do not want your writing to be edited mercilessly, then do not submit it here.
You are also promising us that you wrote this yourself, or copied it from a public domain or similar free resource (see
Encyclopedia:Copyrights
for details).
Do not submit copyrighted work without permission!
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Templates used on this page:
Template:About
(
edit
)
Template:Aspects of capitalism
(
edit
)
Template:Bare URL PDF
(
edit
)
Template:Citation
(
edit
)
Template:Cite book
(
edit
)
Template:Cite journal
(
edit
)
Template:Cite news
(
edit
)
Template:Cite web
(
edit
)
Template:Columns-list
(
edit
)
Template:Commons category
(
edit
)
Template:Critique of political economy
(
edit
)
Template:Critique of political economy sidebar
(
edit
)
Template:Dead link
(
edit
)
Template:Economic systems sidebar
(
edit
)
Template:Feminism sidebar
(
edit
)
Template:Feminist theory
(
edit
)
Template:Globalization
(
edit
)
Template:Good article
(
edit
)
Template:Legend
(
edit
)
Template:Main
(
edit
)
Template:Reflist
(
edit
)
Template:See also
(
edit
)
Template:Short description
(
edit
)
Template:Webarchive
(
edit
)
Search
Search
Editing
Feminist economics
Add topic