Jump to content
Main menu
Main menu
move to sidebar
hide
Navigation
Main page
Recent changes
Random page
Help about MediaWiki
Special pages
Niidae Wiki
Search
Search
Appearance
Create account
Log in
Personal tools
Create account
Log in
Pages for logged out editors
learn more
Contributions
Talk
Editing
Protectionism
(section)
Page
Discussion
English
Read
Edit
View history
Tools
Tools
move to sidebar
hide
Actions
Read
Edit
View history
General
What links here
Related changes
Page information
Appearance
move to sidebar
hide
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
==== United Kingdom==== {{Main article|Economic history of the United Kingdom}} {{See also|British Empire}} {{Conservatism UK}} [[Great Britain]], and England in particular, became one of the most prosperous economic regions in the world between the late 17th century and the early 19th century as a result of being the birthplace of the [[Industrial Revolution]] that began in the mid-eighteenth century.<ref>{{cite book|author=Baten, Jörg |title=A History of the Global Economy. From 1500 to the Present.|date=2016|publisher=Cambridge University Press|page=13|isbn=978-1-107-50718-0}}</ref> The government protected its merchants—and kept others out—by trade barriers, regulations, and subsidies to domestic industries in order to maximize exports from and minimize imports to the realm. The [[Navigation Acts]] of the late 17th century required all trade to be carried in English ships, manned by English crews (this later encompassed all Britons after the [[Acts of Union 1707]] united Scotland with England).<ref>Darwin, 2012 pp. 21–22</ref> Colonists were required to send their produce and raw materials first of all to Britain, where the surplus was then sold-on by British merchants to other colonies in the British empire or bullion-earning external markets. The colonies were forbidden to trade directly with other nations or rival empires. The goal was to maintain the North American and Caribbean colonies as dependent agricultural economies geared towards producing raw materials for export to Britain. The growth of native industry was discouraged, in order to keep the colonies dependent on the United Kingdom for their finished goods.<ref>Darwin, 2012 p. 166</ref><ref>{{cite book|author=Max Savelle|title=Seeds of Liberty: The Genesis of the American Mind|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=hIgl_HNozQsC&pg=PA204|year=1948|page=204ff|publisher=Kessinger |isbn=978-1-4191-0707-8}}</ref> From 1815 to 1870, the United Kingdom reaped the benefits of being the world's first modern, industrialised nation. It described itself as "the workshop of the world", meaning that its finished goods were produced so efficiently and cheaply that they could often undersell comparable, locally manufactured goods in almost any other market.<ref>Harold Cox, ed., ''British industries under free trade'' (1903) pp, 17–18.</ref> By the 1840s, the United Kingdom had adopted a free-trade policy, meaning open markets and no tariffs throughout the empire.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Lynn|first=Martin|year=1999|title=British Policy, Trade, and Informal Empire in the Mid-19th Century|editor-first=Andrew|editor-last=Porter|journal=The Oxford History of the British Empire: Volume III: The Nineteenth Century|volume=3|pages=101–121|doi=10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198205654.003.0006}}</ref> The [[Corn Laws]] were [[tariff]]s and other [[trade restriction]]s on imported food and [[grain|corn]] enforced in the [[United Kingdom of Great Britain and Ireland|United Kingdom]] between 1815 and 1846, and enhanced the profits and political power associated with [[land ownership]]. The laws raised [[food prices]] and the costs of living for the British public, and hampered the growth of other British economic sectors, such as manufacturing, by reducing the disposable income of the British public.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Williamson|first=Jeffrey G|date=1990-04-01|title=The impact of the Corn Laws just prior to repeal|journal=Explorations in Economic History|volume=27|issue=2|pages=123–156|doi=10.1016/0014-4983(90)90007-L}}</ref> The Prime Minister, [[Robert Peel|Sir Robert Peel]], a [[Tories (British political party)|Conservative]], achieved repeal in 1846 with the support of the [[Whigs (British political party)|Whigs]] in Parliament, overcoming the opposition of most of his own party. While the United Kingdom espoused a policy of free trade in the late nineteenth century, it was hardly the case that Britain was unaffected by the tariffs imposed by its trade partners—tariffs that generally increased during the late nineteenth century.<ref>{{Citation |last1=Bairoch |first1=Paul |title=European trade policy, 1815–1914 |date=1989-06-15 |work=The Cambridge Economic History of Europe from the Decline of the Roman Empire |pages=1–160 |editor-last=Mathias |editor-first=Peter |url=https://www.cambridge.org/core/product/identifier/CBO9781139054508A005/type/book_part |access-date=2024-11-06 |edition=1 |publisher=Cambridge University Press |doi=10.1017/chol9780521225045.002 |isbn=978-1-139-05450-8 |last2=Burke |first2=Susan |editor2-last=Pollard |editor2-first=Sidney}}</ref> According to one study, Britain's exports in 1902 would have been 57% higher, if all of Britain's trade partners also embraced free trade.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Varian |first=Brian D. |date=2023 |title=British exports and foreign tariffs: Insights from the Board of Trade's foreign tariff compilation for 1902 |url=https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/ehr.13214 |journal=The Economic History Review |language=en |volume=76 |issue=3 |pages=827–843 |doi=10.1111/ehr.13214 |issn=0013-0117}}</ref> The decline in overseas demand for British exports, resulting from foreign tariffs, contributed to the so-called late-Victorian climacteric in the British economy: a decline in the growth rate, i.e. a deceleration.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Coppock |first=D. J. |date=1956 |title=The Climacteric of the 1890's: A Critical Note |url=https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/j.1467-9957.1956.tb00972.x |journal=The Manchester School |language=en |volume=24 |issue=1 |pages=1–31 |doi=10.1111/j.1467-9957.1956.tb00972.x |issn=1463-6786}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Crafts |first1=Nicholas |last2=Mills |first2=Terence C |date=2020-11-01 |title=Sooner than you think: the Pre-1914 UK Productivity Slowdown was Victorian not Edwardian |url=https://academic.oup.com/ereh/article/24/4/736/5804838 |journal=European Review of Economic History |language=en |volume=24 |issue=4 |pages=736–748 |doi=10.1093/ereh/hez022 |issn=1361-4916|hdl=10.1093/ereh/hez022 |hdl-access=free }}</ref> During the interwar era, Britain abandoned free trade. There was a limited erosion of free trade during the 1920s under a patchwork of legislation including the [[Safeguarding of Industries Act 1921|Safeguarding of Industries Act of 1921]], the [[Safeguarding of Industries (Customs Duties) Act 1925|Safeguarding of Industries Act of 1925]], and the [[Finance Act|Finance Act of 1925]]. The [[Reginald McKenna|McKenna Duties]], which were imposed during the First World War on motorcars; clocks and watches; musical instruments; and cinematographic film were retained.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Abel |first=Deryck |title=A History of British Tariffs, 1923-1942 |publisher=Heath, Cranton Limited |year=1945 |location=London}}</ref> Under commodities that were early to receive protection included matches, chemicals, scientific equipment, silk, rayon, embroidery, lace, cutlery, gloves, incandescent mantles, paper, pottery, enamelled holloware, and buttons.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Varian |first=Brian D. |date=2019 |title=The growth of manufacturing protection in 1920s Britain |url=https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/sjpe.12223 |journal=Scottish Journal of Political Economy |language=en |volume=66 |issue=5 |pages=703–711 |doi=10.1111/sjpe.12223 |issn=0036-9292}}</ref> The duties on motorcars and rayon have been determined to have expanded output considerably.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Foreman-Peck |first=J. S. |date=1979 |title=Tariff Protection and Economies of Scale: The British Motor Industry Before 1939 |url=https://academic.oup.com/oep/article/2360834/TARIFF |journal=Oxford Economic Papers |language=en |volume=31 |issue=2 |pages=237–257 |doi=10.1093/oxfordjournals.oep.a041444 |issn=1464-3812}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal |last=Varian |first=Brian D. |date=2022-08-18 |title=Protection and the British rayon industry during the 1920s |url=https://www.tandfonline.com/doi/full/10.1080/00076791.2020.1753699 |journal=Business History |language=en |volume=64 |issue=6 |pages=1131–1148 |doi=10.1080/00076791.2020.1753699 |issn=0007-6791}}</ref> Amid the Depression, Britain passed the [[Import Duties Act 1932|Import Duties Act of 1932]], which imposed a general tariff of 10% on most imports and created the Import Duties Advisory Committee (IDAC), which could recommend even higher duties.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Abel |first=Deryck |title=A History of British Tariffs, 1923-1942 |publisher=Heath, Cranton Limited |year=1945 |location=London}}</ref> Britain's protectionism in the early 1930s was shown by Lloyd and Solomou to have been productivity-enhancing.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Lloyd |first1=Simon P. |last2=Solomou |first2=Solomos |date=2020 |title=The impact of the 1932 General Tariff: a difference-in-difference approach |url=http://link.springer.com/10.1007/s11698-019-00184-z |journal=Cliometrica |language=en |volume=14 |issue=1 |pages=41–60 |doi=10.1007/s11698-019-00184-z |issn=1863-2505}}</ref> The possessions of the [[East India Company]] in India, known as [[British India]], was the centrepiece of the British Empire, and because of an efficient taxation system it paid its own administrative expenses as well as the cost of the large [[British Indian Army]]. In terms of trade, India turned only a small profit for British business.<ref>P. J. Cain and A. G. Hopkins, ''British Imperialism: 1688–2000'' (2nd ed. 2002) ch. 10</ref> However, transfers to the British government was massive: in 1801 unrequited (unpaid, or paid from Indian-collected revenue) was about 30% of British domestic savings available for capital formation in the United Kingdom.<ref name="jstor.org">{{cite journal |last1=Mukherjee |first1=Aditya |title=Empire: How Colonial India Made Modern Britain |journal=Economic and Political Weekly |date=2010 |volume=45 |issue=50 |pages=73–82 |jstor=25764217}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1=Habib |first1=Irfan |title=Essays in Indian History |date=1995 |publisher=Tulika Press |location=New Delhi |pages=304–46 |chapter=Colonisation of the Indian Economy}}</ref>
Summary:
Please note that all contributions to Niidae Wiki may be edited, altered, or removed by other contributors. If you do not want your writing to be edited mercilessly, then do not submit it here.
You are also promising us that you wrote this yourself, or copied it from a public domain or similar free resource (see
Encyclopedia:Copyrights
for details).
Do not submit copyrighted work without permission!
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Search
Search
Editing
Protectionism
(section)
Add topic