Jump to content
Main menu
Main menu
move to sidebar
hide
Navigation
Main page
Recent changes
Random page
Help about MediaWiki
Special pages
Niidae Wiki
Search
Search
Appearance
Create account
Log in
Personal tools
Create account
Log in
Pages for logged out editors
learn more
Contributions
Talk
Editing
Herfindahl–Hirschman index
(section)
Page
Discussion
English
Read
Edit
View history
Tools
Tools
move to sidebar
hide
Actions
Read
Edit
View history
General
What links here
Related changes
Page information
Appearance
move to sidebar
hide
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
==Intuition== When all the firms in an industry have equal market shares, <math display="inline">H = N\left( \dfrac{1}{N} \right)^2 = \dfrac{1}{N}</math>. The Herfindahl is correlated with the number of firms in an industry because its lower bound when there are ''N'' firms is 1/''N''. In the more general case of unequal market share, 1/''H'' is called "equivalent (or effective) number of firms in the industry", ''N''<sub>eqi</sub> or ''N''<sub>eff</sub>.<ref>{{cite journal|title=A Generalized Interpretation of the Herfindahl Index|last=Kelly, Jr.|first=William A.|journal=Southern Economic Journal|date=July 1981|volume=48|number=1|pages=50–57|publisher=[[Southern Economic Association]]|doi=10.2307/1058595 |jstor=1058595}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal|title=Comment on the "H" Concentration Measure as a Numbers-Equivalent|last=Adelman|first=M. A.|date=February 1969|volume=51|number=1|journal=[[The Review of Economics and Statistics]]|publisher=[[MIT Press|The MIT Press]]|pages=99–101|doi=10.2307/1926955 |jstor=1926955}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal|title=Elasticities, Cross-Elasticities, and Market Relationships|last=Bishop|first=Robert L.|journal=[[The American Economic Review]]|date=December 1952|volume=42|number=5|pages=780–803|publisher=[[American Economic Association]]|jstor=1812527}}</ref> An industry with 3 firms cannot have a lower Herfindahl than an industry with 20 firms when firms have equal market shares. But as market shares of the 20-firm industry diverge from equality the Herfindahl can exceed that of the equal-market-share 3-firm industry (e.g., if one firm has 81% of the market and the remaining 19 have 1% each, then <math>H=0.658</math>). A higher Herfindahl signifies a less competitive (i.e., more concentrated) industry. === Appearance in market structure === It can be shown that the Herfindahl index arises as a natural consequence of assuming that a given market's structure is described by [[Cournot competition]].<ref>{{Cite book|url=https://mitpress.mit.edu/9780262038065/economics-of-regulation-and-antitrust/|url-access=subscription|title=Economics of Regulation and Antitrust|last1=Viscusi|first1=W. Kip|author-link1=W. Kip Viscusi|last2=Harrington, Jr.|first2=Joseph Emmett|last3=Sappington|first3=David Edward Michael|publisher=[[MIT Press|The MIT Press]]|year=2018|isbn=9780262038065|edition=Fifth|location=[[Cambridge, Massachusetts]]|pages=177–178|lccn=2017056198}}</ref> Suppose that we have a Cournot model for competition between <math>n</math> firms with different linear marginal costs and a homogeneous product. Then the profit of the <math>i</math>-th firm <math>\pi_{i}</math> is: <math display="block">\pi_{i} = P(Q)q_{i} - c_{i}q_{i}, \quad Q = \sum_{i=1}^{n}q_{i} </math> where <math>q_{i}</math> is the quantity produced by each firm, <math>c_{i}</math> is the [[marginal cost]] of production for each firm, and <math>P(Q)</math> is the price of the product. Taking the derivative of the firm's profit function with respect to its output to maximize its profit gives us: <math display="block">\frac{\partial\pi_i}{\partial q_i} = 0 \implies P'(Q)q_{i} + P(Q) - c_{i} = 0 \implies - \frac{dP}{dQ} q_{i} = P-c_{i} </math> Dividing by <math>P</math> gives us each firm's [[profit margin]]: <math display="block">{P-c_{i}\over{P}} = -{dP\over{dQ}}{q_{i}\over{P}} = -{dP/P\over{dQ/Q}} {q_{i}\over{Q}} = {s_{i}\over{\eta}} </math> where <math>s_{i} = q_{i}/Q</math> is the market share and <math>\eta = -d\log Q/d\log P</math> is the [[price elasticity of demand]]. Multiplying each firm's profit margin by its market share gives us: <math display="block">s_{1}\left( {P-c_{1}\over{P}} \right) + \cdots + s_{n}\left( {P-c_{n}\over{P}} \right) = {H\over{\eta}}</math> where <math>H</math> is the Herfindahl index. Therefore, the Herfindahl index is directly related to the weighted average of the profit margins of firms under Cournot competition with linear marginal costs. === Effective assets in a portfolio === The Herfindahl index is also a widely used metric for [[Portfolio (finance)|portfolio]] concentration.<ref>{{cite book|last=Lovett|first=William Anthony|title=Banking and Financial Institutions Law in a Nutshell|year=1988|publisher=West Publishing Company|edition=2nd|isbn=9780314414434}}</ref> In portfolio theory, the Herfindahl index is related to the effective number of positions <math>N_{\text{eff}} = 1/H</math><ref>{{cite arXiv|last1=Bouchaud|first1=Jean-Philippe|last2=Potters|first2=Marc|last3=Aguilar|first3=Jean-Pierre|title=Missing Information and Asset Allocation|date=July 1997|eprint=cond-mat/9707042}}{{bibcode|1997cond.mat..7042B}}</ref> held in a portfolio, where <math display="inline">H = \sum \|w\|^{2}</math> is computed as the sum of the squares of the proportion of market value invested in each security. A low H-index implies a very diversified portfolio: as an example, a portfolio with <math>H = 0.02</math> is equivalent to a portfolio with <math>N_{\text{eff}} = 50</math> equally weighted positions. The H-index has been shown to be one of the most efficient measures of portfolio diversification.<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Woerheide|first1=Walt J.|last2=Persson|first2=Don|year=1993|title=An Index of Portfolio Diversification|url=https://pdfs.semanticscholar.org/0a5e/ec924dae3ea30b6cae8e66f7070344d47631.pdf|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180323220210/https://pdfs.semanticscholar.org/0a5e/ec924dae3ea30b6cae8e66f7070344d47631.pdf|url-access=subscription|url-status=dead|archive-date=2018-03-23| journal=Financial Services Review|volume=2|issue=2|pages=73–85|doi=10.1016/1057-0810(92)90003-U|s2cid=18548005|issn=1057-0810}}</ref> It may also be used as a [[Constraint (mathematics)|constraint]] to force a portfolio to hold a minimum number of effective assets: <math display="block">\|w\|^{2} \leq N_{\text{eff}}^{-1}</math> For commonly used [[portfolio optimization]] techniques, such as [[Modern portfolio theory|mean-variance]] and [[Expected shortfall|CVaR]], the optimal solution may be found using [[second-order cone programming]].
Summary:
Please note that all contributions to Niidae Wiki may be edited, altered, or removed by other contributors. If you do not want your writing to be edited mercilessly, then do not submit it here.
You are also promising us that you wrote this yourself, or copied it from a public domain or similar free resource (see
Encyclopedia:Copyrights
for details).
Do not submit copyrighted work without permission!
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Search
Search
Editing
Herfindahl–Hirschman index
(section)
Add topic