Jump to content
Main menu
Main menu
move to sidebar
hide
Navigation
Main page
Recent changes
Random page
Help about MediaWiki
Special pages
Niidae Wiki
Search
Search
Appearance
Create account
Log in
Personal tools
Create account
Log in
Pages for logged out editors
learn more
Contributions
Talk
Editing
Financial economics
(section)
Page
Discussion
English
Read
Edit
View history
Tools
Tools
move to sidebar
hide
Actions
Read
Edit
View history
General
What links here
Related changes
Page information
Appearance
move to sidebar
hide
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
===State prices=== With the above relationship established, the further specialized [[Arrow–Debreu model]] may be derived. {{NoteTag|State prices originate with [[Kenneth Arrow]] and [[Gérard Debreu]] in 1954.<ref>{{cite journal | last1 = Arrow | first1 = K. J. | last2 = Debreu | first2 = G. | year = 1954 | title = Existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy | journal = Econometrica | volume = 22 | issue =3 | pages = 265–290 | doi = 10.2307/1907353 | jstor = 1907353 }}</ref> [[Lionel W. McKenzie]] is also cited for his independent proof of equilibrium existence in 1954.<ref>{{cite journal |first=Lionel W. |last=McKenzie |title=On Equilibrium in Graham's Model of World Trade and Other Competitive Systems |journal=Econometrica |year=1954 |volume=22 |issue=2 |pages=147–161 |jstor=1907539 |doi=10.2307/1907539}}</ref> [[Douglas Breeden|Breeden]] and [[Robert Litzenberger|Litzenberger's]] work in 1978<ref>{{cite journal |title=Prices of State-Contingent Claims Implicit in Option Prices |first1=Douglas T. |last1=Breeden |author-link=Douglas Breeden|first2=Robert H. |last2=Litzenberger |author2-link=Robert Litzenberger |journal=[[Journal of Business]] |volume=51 |issue=4 |year=1978 |pages=621–651 |jstor=2352653 |doi=10.1086/296025|s2cid=153841737 }}</ref> established the use of state prices in financial economics.}} This result suggests that, under certain economic conditions, there must be a set of prices such that aggregate supplies will equal aggregate demands for every commodity in the economy. The Arrow–Debreu model applies to economies with maximally [[complete market]]s, in which there exists a market for every time period and forward prices for every commodity at all time periods. A direct extension, then, is the concept of a [[state price]] security, also called an Arrow–Debreu security, a contract that agrees to pay one unit of a [[numeraire]] (a currency or a commodity) if a particular state occurs ("up" and "down" in the simplified example above) at a particular time in the future and pays zero numeraire in all the other states. The price of this security is the ''state price'' <math>\pi_{s}</math> of this particular state of the world; the collection of these is also referred to as a "Risk Neutral Density".<ref name="Figlewski"/> In the above example, the state prices, <math>\pi_{up}</math>, <math>\pi_{down}</math>would equate to the present values of <math>$q_{up}</math> and <math>$q_{down}</math>: i.e. what one would pay today, respectively, for the up- and down-state securities; the [[state price vector]] is the vector of state prices for all states. Applied to derivative valuation, the price today would simply be {{Nowrap|[<math>\pi_{up}</math>×<math>X_{up}</math> + <math>\pi_{down}</math>×<math>X_{down}</math>]}}: the fourth formula (see above regarding the absence of a risk premium here). For a [[continuous random variable]] indicating a continuum of possible states, the value is found by [[integration (mathematics)|integrating]] over the state price "density". State prices find immediate application as a conceptual tool ("[[contingent claim analysis]]");<ref name="Rubinstein"/> but can also be applied to valuation problems.<ref name="corp fin state prices">See de Matos, as well as Bossaerts and Ødegaard, under bibliography.</ref> Given the pricing mechanism described, one can decompose the derivative value – true in fact for "every security"<ref name="Miller"/> – as a linear combination of its state-prices; i.e. back-solve for the state-prices corresponding to observed derivative prices.<ref name="Chance2"/><ref name="corp fin state prices"/> <ref name="Figlewski">{{cite journal | last1 = Figlewski | first1 = Stephen | year = 2018 | title = Risk-Neutral Densities: A Review Annual Review of Financial Economics | journal = [[Annual Review of Financial Economics]] | volume = 10 | pages = 329–359| doi = 10.1146/annurev-financial-110217-022944 | ssrn = 3120028 | s2cid = 158075926 |url=https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3120028}}</ref> These recovered state-prices can then be used for valuation of other instruments with exposure to the underlyer, or for other decision making relating to the underlyer itself. Using the related [[stochastic discount factor]] - SDF; also called the pricing kernel - the asset price is computed by "discounting" the future cash flow by the stochastic factor <math>\tilde{m}</math>, and then taking the expectation;<ref name="Backus">See: [[David K. Backus]] (2015). [http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/233/notes_econ_assetpricing.pdf Fundamentals of Asset Pricing], Stern NYU</ref><ref>Lars Peter Hansen & Eric Renault (2020). [https://larspeterhansen.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/10/Pricing-Kernels-and-Stochastic-Discount-Factors.pdf "Pricing Kernels"] in: ''Encyclopedia of Quantitative Finance''. {{ISBN|0470057564}}</ref> the third equation above. Essentially, this factor divides expected [[Utility#Expected_utility|utility]] at the relevant future period - a function of the possible asset values realized under each state - by the utility due to today's wealth, and is then also referred to as "the intertemporal [[marginal rate of substitution]]". Correspondingly, the SDF, <math>\tilde{m}_{s}</math>, may be thought of as the discounted value of Risk Aversion, <math>Y_{s}.</math> (The latter may be inferred via the ratio of risk neutral- to physical-probabilities, <math>q_{s} / p_{s}.</math> See [[Girsanov theorem]] and [[Radon-Nikodym derivative]].)
Summary:
Please note that all contributions to Niidae Wiki may be edited, altered, or removed by other contributors. If you do not want your writing to be edited mercilessly, then do not submit it here.
You are also promising us that you wrote this yourself, or copied it from a public domain or similar free resource (see
Encyclopedia:Copyrights
for details).
Do not submit copyrighted work without permission!
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Search
Search
Editing
Financial economics
(section)
Add topic