Jump to content
Main menu
Main menu
move to sidebar
hide
Navigation
Main page
Recent changes
Random page
Help about MediaWiki
Special pages
Niidae Wiki
Search
Search
Appearance
Create account
Log in
Personal tools
Create account
Log in
Pages for logged out editors
learn more
Contributions
Talk
Editing
Commercial revolution
(section)
Page
Discussion
English
Read
Edit
View history
Tools
Tools
move to sidebar
hide
Actions
Read
Edit
View history
General
What links here
Related changes
Page information
Appearance
move to sidebar
hide
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
==Colonialism and mercantilism== {{Further|Mercantilism}} {{Further|Age of Discovery}} [[Image:Portuguese discoveries and explorationsV2en.png|thumb|300px|[[Portuguese discoveries]] and explorations from 1415 to 1543: first arrival places and dates; main Portuguese [[spice trade]] routes in the Indian Ocean (in blue); territories of the [[Portuguese Empire]] under the rule of [[King John III of Portugal|King John III]] (1521–1557) (in green).]] The deterioration of the climate that brought about the end of the [[medieval warm period]] (or medieval weather anomaly) caused an economic decline at the beginning of the 14th century (see [[Great Famine of 1315–17|Great Famine]]). However, demographic expansion continued until the arrival of the [[Black Death]] epidemic in 1347, when ca. 50% of the European population was killed by the plague. The economic effects of a labor shortage actually caused wages to rise, while agricultural yields were once again able to support a diminished population. By the beginning of the 15th century, the economic expansion associated with the commercial revolution in earlier centuries returned in full force, aided by improvements in navigation and cartography. Geopolitical, monetary, and technological factors drove the Age of Discovery. During this period (1450–17th century), the European economic center shifted from the Islamic [[Mediterranean]] to Western Europe (Portugal, Spain, France, the Netherlands, and to some extent England). This shift was caused by the successful [[circumnavigation]] of Africa, which opened up sea-trade with the east: after Portugal's [[Vasco da Gama]] rounded the [[Cape of Good Hope]] and landed in [[Kozhikode|Calicut]], India in May 1498, a new path of eastern trade was possible, ending the monopoly of the Ottoman Turks and the Italian city-states.<ref name=Columbia1>[http://www.bartleby.com/65/ga/Gama-Vas.html Gama, Vasco da. The Columbia Encyclopedia, Sixth Edition. Columbia University Press.] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20090214112314/http://www.bartleby.com/65/ga/Gama-Vas.html |date=2009-02-14 }}</ref> The wealth of the [[Indies]] was now open for the Europeans to explore; the [[Portuguese Empire]] was one of the early European empires to grow from spice trade.<ref name=Columbia1/> Following this, Portugal became the controlling state for trade between east and west, followed later by the Dutch city of [[Antwerp]]. Direct maritime trade between Europe and China started in the 16th century, after the Portuguese established the settlement of [[Goa]], India in December 1510, and thereafter that of [[Macau]] in southern China in 1557. Since the English came late to the transatlantic trade,<ref>{{cite book| author=Fisk, John | publisher=Houghton Mifflin and Company |page=14|year=1900 | title=Old Virginia and Her Neighbours }}</ref> their commercial revolution was later as well. ===Geopolitical factors=== In 1453, the [[Ottoman Empire|Ottoman Turks]] took over [[Constantinople]], which cut off (or significantly increased the cost of) overland trade routes between Europe and the Far East,<ref>{{cite book |title=New York: the World's Capital City, Its Development and Contributions to Progress |url=https://archive.org/details/in.ernet.dli.2015.226262 |chapter=Chapter 1 |author=Rankin, Rebecca B., Cleveland Rodgers |publisher=Harper |year=1948}}</ref> so alternative routes had to be found. English laws were changed to benefit the navy, but had commercial implications in terms of farming. These laws also contributed to the demise of the [[Hanseatic League]], which traded in northern Europe.<ref>{{cite book | title=The Growth of English Industry and Commerce in Modern Times | author= Cunningham, William | author-link= William Cunningham (economist) | page= 26 | year=1892 | publisher = University Press}}</ref> Because of the [[Reconquista]], the Spanish had a warrior culture ready to conquer still more people and places, so Spain was perfectly positioned to develop their [[Spanish Empire|vast overseas empire]].<ref name="isbn0-449-90496-2">{{cite book |author=Weatherford, J. McIver |author-link=J. McIver Weatherford |title=Indian givers: how the Indians of the Americas transformed the world |publisher=Fawcett Columbine |location=New York |year=1988 |page=[https://archive.org/details/indiangivershow000weat/page/231 231] |isbn=0-449-90496-2 |url=https://archive.org/details/indiangivershow000weat/page/231 }}</ref> Rivalry between the European powers produced intense competition for the creation of colonial empires, and fueled the rush to sail out of Europe.<ref>{{Cite book | last1 = Diamond | first1 = Jared M. | title = Guns, germs, and steel: the fates of human societies | url = https://archive.org/details/gunsgermssteelfa0000diam | url-access = registration | year = 1997 | publisher = W.W. Norton | location = New York | isbn = 0-393-03891-2 }} </ref> ===Monetary factors=== The need for silver coinage also affected the desire for expanded exploration as silver and gold were spent for trade to the Middle and Far East. The Europeans had a constant deficit in that silver and gold coin only went one way: out of Europe, spent on the very type of trade that they were now cut off from by the Ottomans. Another issue was that European mines were exhausted of silver ore and gold. What ore remained was too deep to recover, as water would fill the mine, and technology was not sufficiently advanced enough to successfully remove the water to get to the ore or gold.<ref>{{cite web | url=http://www-geology.ucdavis.edu/~cowen/~GEL115/115CH7.html | title=Exploiting the Earth | access-date=2007-10-17 | author=Cowen, Richard | url-status=dead | archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20071009180929/http://www-geology.ucdavis.edu/~cowen/~GEL115/115CH7.html | archive-date=2007-10-09 }}</ref> A second argument is that trade during the youth of the commercial revolution blossomed not due to explorations for bullion (gold and silver coinings) but due to a newfound faith in gold coinage. Italian city-states such as Genoa and Florence (where the first gold coins began to be minted in 1252) and kingdoms such as the Kingdom of Sicily routinely received gold through such trading partners as Tunisia and Senegal.<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Lopez|first1=Robert S.|title=Back to Gold, 1252|journal=The Economic History Review|date=1956|volume=9|issue=2|pages=219–240|doi=10.2307/2591743|jstor=2591743 }}<!--|access-date=6 November 2014--></ref> A new, stable and universally accepted coinage that was both compatible with traditional European coinage systems and serviced the increased demand for currency to facilitate trade made it even more lucrative to carry out trade with the rest of the world. ===Technological factors=== [[File:Theatrum Orbis Terrarum, by Abraham Ortelius, World, 1572.jpg|thumb|In 1570 (May 20) Gilles Coppens de Diest at [[Antwerp]] published 53 maps created by [[Abraham Ortelius]] under the title ''[[Theatrum Orbis Terrarum]]'', considered the "first modern atlas". Latin editions, besides Dutch, French and German editions appeared before the end of 1572; the atlas continued to be in demand until about 1612. This is the world map from this atlas.]] From the 16th to 18th centuries, Europeans made remarkable maritime [[innovation]]s. These innovations enabled them to expand overseas and set up colonies, most notably during the 16th and 17th centuries. They developed new [[sail]] arrangements for ships, skeleton-based shipbuilding,<ref>{{cite book |author=Marcus Rautman |title=Daily life in the Byzantine Empire |publisher=Greenwood Press |location=Westport, Conn |year=2006 |page=150 |isbn=0-313-32437-9 }}</ref> the Western "galea" (at the end of the 11th century), sophisticated navigational instruments, and detailed [[chart]]s and maps. After Isaac Newton published the ''[[Philosophiae Naturalis Principia Mathematica|Principia]]'', navigation was transformed, because sailors could predict the motion of the moon and other [[celestial object]]s using Newton's theories of motion.<ref>{{cite book | title=The Family Magazine| page=436 | year=1838 | publisher=Redfield & Lindsay}}</ref> Starting in 1670, the entire world was measured using essentially modern latitude instruments. In 1676, the British Parliament declared that navigation was the greatest scientific problem of the age and in 1714 offered a substantial [[Longitude rewards|financial prize]] for the solution to finding longitude. This spurred the development of the [[marine chronometer]], the [[lunar distance method]] and the invention of the [[octant (instrument)|octant]] after 1730.<ref>{{cite book |author=Haven, Kendall F. |title=100 Greatest Science Inventions of All Time |publisher=Libraries Unlimited |location=Littleton, Colo |year= 2006|page=69 |isbn= 1-59158-264-4 }}</ref> By the late 18th century, navigators replaced their prior instruments with octants and sextants. ===Important people=== Significant contributors to European exploration include Prince [[Henry the Navigator]] of Portugal, who was the first of the Europeans to venture out into the Atlantic Ocean, in 1420. Others are [[Bartolomeu Dias]], who first rounded the [[Cape of Good Hope]]; [[Vasco da Gama]], who sailed directly to India from Portugal; [[Ferdinand Magellan]], the first to circumnavigate the Earth; [[Christopher Columbus]], who significantly encountered the Americas; [[Jacques Cartier]], who sailed for France, looking for the [[Northwest Passage]];<ref>{{cite book |title = Jacques Cartier, his life and voyages |url = https://archive.org/details/jacquescartierhi00popeuoft |last = Pope | first = Joseph | publisher= Printed by A.S. Woodburn | year = 1890 | page = [https://archive.org/details/jacquescartierhi00popeuoft/page/49 49]}}</ref> and others. ===Key Features=== The economy of the [[Roman Empire]] had been based on [[Roman currency|money]], but after the Empire's fall, money became scarce; power and wealth became strictly land based, and local [[fief]]s were (at least theoretically) self-sufficient. Because trade was dangerous and expensive, there were not many traders, and not much trade. The scarcity of money did not help;<ref name="webster">{{cite book |author=Webster, Hutton |author-link=Hutton Webster |title=Medieval and Modern History|url=https://archive.org/details/medievalandmode01websgoog |publisher=D.C. Heath & Co |year=1919 |location= Boston}}</ref> however, the European economic system had begun to change in the 14th century, partially as a result of the [[Black Death]], and the [[Crusades]].<ref name="lewis">{{cite book|author=Lewis, Archibald|title=Nomads and Crusaders: AD 1000–1368.|date=January 1988|publisher=Indiana University Press|isbn=978-0-253-20652-7}}</ref> Banks, stock exchanges, and insurance became ways to manage the risk involved in the renewed trade. New laws came into being.{{clarify |date=July 2016 |reason= Which laws, and in which countries?}} Travel became safer as nations developed. Economic theories{{clarify |date=July 2016 |reason= Which theories?}} began to develop in light of all of the new trading activity. The commercial revolution is also marked by the formalization of pre-existing, informal methods of dealing with trade and commerce. ===Inflation=== {{Further|Price revolution}} [[File:Potosì 8 reales 1768 131206.jpg|thumb|right|[[Potosí]] (Bolivia) silver 8 reales, Carlos III, 1768]] [[File:doubloon.jpg|thumb|right|Spanish gold [[doubloon]] stamped as minted in 1798]] [[Habsburg Spain|Spain]] legally amassed approximately 180 [[ton]]s of gold and 8200 tons of silver through its endeavors in the [[New World]], and another unknown amount through smuggling,<ref>{{cite book |author=Walton, Timothy R. |title=The Spanish Treasure Fleets |publisher=Pineapple Press (FL) |year= 1994|page=85 |isbn=1-56164-049-2 }}</ref> spending this money to finance wars and the arts. The spent silver, suddenly being spread throughout a previously cash starved Europe, caused widespread inflation.<ref>{{cite book |author=Tracy, James D. |title=Handbook of European History 1400–1600: Late Middle Ages, Renaissance, and Reformation |publisher=Brill Academic Publishers |location=Boston |year= 1994|page=655 |isbn=90-04-09762-7 }}</ref> The inflation was worsened by a growing population but a static production level, low employee salaries and a rising cost of living. This problem, combined with [[underpopulation]] (caused by the [[Black Death]]), affected the system of agriculture. The landholding aristocracy suffered under the inflation, since they depended on paying small, fixed wages to peasant tenants that were becoming able to demand higher wages.<ref name = "Cunningham">{{cite book | title=The Growth of English Industry and Commerce in Modern Times | url=https://archive.org/details/growthenglishin01cunngoog | author= Cunningham, William| page= [https://archive.org/details/growthenglishin01cunngoog/page/n35 15] | year=1892 | publisher = University Press}}</ref> The aristocracy made failed attempts to counteract this situation by creating short-term leases of their lands to allow periodic revaluation of rent. The [[manorial system]] (manor system of lord and peasant tenant) eventually vanished, and the landholding [[Aristocracy (class)|aristocrats]] were forced to sell pieces of their land to maintain their style of living.<ref>{{cite book |author=Danbom, David B. |title=Born in the Country: A History of Rural America (Revisiting Rural America) |publisher=The Johns Hopkins University Press |location=Baltimore |year=2006 |page=4 |isbn=0-8018-8459-4 }}</ref> Such sales transferred ownership to wealthy commoners, who wanted to buy land and thereby increase their social status. Former "common lands" were fenced by the landed gentry, a process known as "[[enclosure]]" which subsidized the cost of raising livestock (mainly sheep's wool for the [[textile industry]]). This "enclosure" forced the peasants out of rural areas and into the cities, resulting in urbanization. The increase in the availability of silver coin allowed for commerce to expand in numerous ways.<ref>{{cite book |author=Weatherford, J. McIver |author-link=J. McIver Weatherford |title=Indian givers: how the Indians of the Americas transformed the world |publisher=Fawcett Columbine |location=New York |year=1988 |page=[https://archive.org/details/indiangivershow000weat/page/15 15] |isbn=0-449-90496-2 |url=https://archive.org/details/indiangivershow000weat/page/15 }}</ref> ===Banks=== {{Further|History of banking}} [[Image:Matsys the moneylender.jpg|left|thumb|''The Moneylender and his Wife'' (1514)<br/> Oil on panel, 71 x 68 cm [[Musée du Louvre]], Paris]] Various legal and religious developments in the late Middle Ages allowed for development of the modern banking system at the beginning of the 16th century. Interest was allowed to be charged, and [[Profit (economics)|profits]] generated from holding other people's money. Banks in the Italian Peninsula had great difficulty operating at the end of the 14th century, for lack of silver and gold coin.<ref name="isbn0-521-37590-8">{{cite book |author=Spufford, Peter |title=Money and its Use in Medieval Europe |url=https://archive.org/details/moneyitsusemedie00spuf |url-access=limited |publisher=Cambridge University Press |location=Cambridge, UK |year= 1993|page=[https://archive.org/details/moneyitsusemedie00spuf/page/n362 349] |isbn=0-521-37590-8 }}</ref> Nevertheless, by the later 16th century, enough bullion was available that many more people could keep a small amount hoarded and used as [[Capital (economics)|capital]].<ref>{{cite book | title=The Growth of English Industry and Commerce in Modern Times | url=https://archive.org/details/growthenglishin01cunngoog | author= Cunningham, William| page= [https://archive.org/details/growthenglishin01cunngoog/page/n34 14] | year=1892 | publisher = University Press}}</ref> In response to this extra available money, northern European banking interests came along; among them was the [[Fugger]] family. The Fuggers were originally weavers and cloth merchants, but soon became involved in banking, charging interest, and other financial activities. They dealt with everyone, from small-time individuals, to the highest nobility. Their banks even loaned to the emperors and kings, eventually going bankrupt when their clients defaulted.<ref>{{cite book |author=Brechin, Gray A.|author-link=Gray Brechin|title=Imperial San Francisco: urban power, earthly ruin |publisher=University of California Press |location=Berkeley |year=1999 |isbn=0-520-22902-9 }}</ref> This family, and other individuals, used Italian methods which outpaced the [[Hanseatic League]]'s ability to keep up with the changes occurring in northern Europe.<ref>{{cite book | title=The Growth of English Industry and Commerce in Modern Times | url=https://archive.org/details/growthenglishin01cunngoog | author= Cunningham, William| page= [https://archive.org/details/growthenglishin01cunngoog/page/n44 24] | year=1892 | publisher = University Press}}</ref> Antwerp had one of the first money exchanges in Europe, a [[Exchange (organized market)|Bourse]], where people could change currency. After the [[Siege of Antwerp (1584-1585)]], the majority of business transactions were moved to Amsterdam. The [[Bank of Amsterdam]], following the example of a private [[Stockholm]] corporation, began issuing [[paper money]] to lessen the difficulty of trade, replacing metal (coin and bullion) in exchanges. In 1609 the ''[[Amsterdamsche Wisselbank]]'' (Amsterdam Exchange Bank) was founded which made Amsterdam the financial center of the world until the [[Industrial Revolution]]. In a notable example of crossover between stock companies and banks, the [[Bank of England]], which opened in 1694, was a joint-stock company.<ref>{{cite book |author=Keyser, Henry |title=The law relating to transactions on the stock exchange |publisher=Oxford University Press |location=Oxford [Oxfordshire] |year=1850 |page=1 }}</ref> Banking offices were usually located near centers of trade, and in the late 17th century, the largest centers for commerce were the ports of [[Amsterdam]], London, and [[Hamburg]]. Individuals could participate in the lucrative [[East India]] trade by purchasing bills of credit from these banks, but the price they received for commodities was dependent on the ships returning (which often did not happen on time) and on the cargo they carried (which often was not according to plan). The commodities market was very volatile for this reason, and also because of the many wars that led to cargo seizures and loss of ships. ===Managing risk=== Trade in this period was a risky business: war, weather, and other uncertainties often kept merchants from making a profit, and frequently an entire cargo would disappear all together. To mitigate this risk, the wealthy got together to share the risk through stock: people would own shares of a venture, so that if there was a loss, it would not be an all consuming loss costing the individual investor everything in one transaction.<ref>{{cite book | author=Day, Clive |title=A History of Commerce | url=https://archive.org/details/commerchistory00daycrich | page=[https://archive.org/details/commerchistory00daycrich/page/144 144] | publisher = Longmans, Green, and Co |year= 1914}}</ref> Other ways of dealing with the risk and expense associated with all of the new trade activity include insurance and [[Joint-stock company|joint stock companies]] which were created as formal institutions. People had been informally sharing risk for hundreds of years, but the formal ways they were now sharing risk was new.<ref name="isbn0-19-829508-1">{{cite book |author=Michie, R. C. |title=The London Stock Exchange: a history |publisher=Oxford University Press |location=Oxford [Oxfordshire] |year=1999 |page=34 |isbn=0-19-829508-1 }}</ref> Even though the ruling classes would not often directly assist in trade endeavors, and individuals were unequal to the task,<ref>{{cite book| author=Fisk, John | publisher=Houghton Mifflin and Company |page=182|year=1900 | title=Old Virginia and Her Neighbours }}</ref> rulers such as [[Henry VIII of England]] established a permanent Royal Navy, with the intention of reducing piracy, and protecting English shipping.<ref>{{cite book| author=Lindsay, William S. | title=History of Merchant Shipping and ancient commerce |publisher=Sampson Low, Marston, Low, and Searle | location=London |year=1872 |page=89}}</ref> ====Joint stock companies and stock exchanges==== [[Image:Royal Exchange 1760.jpg|thumb|Plan of the London Royal Exchange in 1760]] [[Stock exchange]]s were developed as the volume of stock transactions increased. The London [[Royal Exchange (London)|Royal Exchange]] established in 1565 first developed as a securities market, though by 1801 it had become a stock exchange.<ref name="isbn0-19-829508-1"/> Historian [[Fernand Braudel]] suggests that in [[Cairo]] in the 11th-century Muslim and Jewish merchants had already set up every form of [[trade association]] and had knowledge of every method of credit and payment, disproving the belief that these were invented later by Italians. In 12th century France the ''courratiers de change'' were concerned with managing and regulating the debts of agricultural communities on behalf of the banks. Because these men also traded with debts, they could be called the first [[stockbroker|broker]]s. In late 13th century [[Bruges]] commodity traders gathered inside the house of a man called ''Van der Beurse'', and in 1309 they became the "Bruges Beurse", institutionalizing what had been, until then, an informal meeting. The idea quickly spread around [[Flanders]] and neighboring counties and "Beurzen" soon opened in [[Ghent]] and [[Amsterdam]].<ref name="common_sense_aint_common">{{Cite book | last1 = Shane Darrisaw | first1 = H. | title = Common Sense Ain't Common: A guide for positioning yourself to take full advantage of your credit and financial opportunities! | date = March 2008 | publisher = AuthorHouse | isbn = 978-1-4343-7559-9 | page = 86 }}</ref> "In the middle of the 13th century [[Venice|Venetian]] bankers began to trade in [[Government debt|government securities]]. In 1351 the Venetian government outlawed spreading rumors intended to lower the price of government funds."<ref name="common_sense_aint_common"/> Bankers in [[Pisa]], [[Verona]], [[Genoa]] and [[Florence]] also began trading in government securities during the 14th century. This practice was only possible, because these independent city states were not ruled by a duke but a council of influential citizens. The Dutch later started [[Joint-stock company|joint stock companies]], which let [[shareholder]]s invest in business ventures and get a share of their profits – or losses. In 1602, the [[Dutch East India Company]] issued the first shares on the [[Amsterdam Stock Exchange]]. It was the first company to issue stocks and bonds.<ref>{{cite web | last = Chambers | first = Clem | title = Who needs stock exchanges? | url = http://www.exchange-handbook.co.uk/index.cfm?section=articles&action=detail&id=60613 | publisher = Mondo Visione | access-date = 25 October 2009 }}</ref> The [[Amsterdam Stock Exchange]] (or Amsterdam Beurs) is also said to have been the first stock exchange to introduce continuous trade in the early 17th century. The Dutch "pioneered [[Short (finance)|short selling]], [[Options strategies|option trading]], debt-equity swaps, [[merchant bank]]ing, unit [[Trust law|trusts]] and other [[Speculation|speculative instruments]], much as we know them."<ref>{{cite web | last = Sayle | first = Murray | title = LRB · Murray Sayle: Japan goes Dutch | url = http://www.lrb.co.uk/v23/n07/sayl01_.html | publisher = London Review of Books XXIII.7 | date = 5 April 2001 | access-date = 25 October 2009 }}</ref> ====Insurance companies==== [[image:Insurance Contact 2.jpg|thumb|right|A sample insurance contract. Documents such as this helped traders survive losses.]] Insurance companies were another way to mitigate risk. Insurance in one form or another has been around as far back as there are records. What differed about insurance going into the 16th and 17th centuries was that these informal mechanisms became formalized. [[Lloyd's of London]] came into being in 1688 in English coffee shops that catered to sailors, traders, and others involved in trade. Lloyd's coffeehouse published a newspaper, which gave news from various parts of the world, and helped the underwriters of the insurance at the coffeehouse to determine the risk.<ref>{{cite book| title= The History of Lloyd's and of Marine Insurance in Great Britain| url= https://archive.org/details/historyoflloydso00martuoft| author= Martin, Frederick|year=1876|publisher = MacMillan and Company, London|pages=[https://archive.org/details/historyoflloydso00martuoft/page/65 65]–80}}</ref> This innovation was one of many that allowed for the categorization of risk. Another innovation was the use of ship catalogs and classifications. Other forms of insurance began to appear as well. After the [[Great Fire of London]], [[Nicholas Barbon]] began to sell fire insurance in 1667.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.london-fire.gov.uk/about_us/our_history/key_dates.asp |title=London Fire Brigade – History, key dates (Our history) |access-date=2007-10-27 |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080618055617/http://www.london-fire.gov.uk/about_us/our_history/key_dates.asp |archive-date=2008-06-18 }}</ref> Laws were changed to deal with insurance issues, such as ''[[Ordinance of Marine|l'Ordonnance de la Marine]]'' (by Colbert in 1681).<ref name="isbn1-84542-013-6">{{cite book |author=Smits, Jan |title=Elgar Encyclopedia of Comparative Law (Elgar Original Reference) |url=https://archive.org/details/elgarencyclopedi00smit_487 |url-access=limited |publisher=Edward Elgar Publishing |year= 2006|page=[https://archive.org/details/elgarencyclopedi00smit_487/page/n333 315] |isbn=1-84542-013-6 }}</ref> ===Economic theory=== {{Further|History of Economic Thought}} As the economy grew through the commercial revolution, so did attempts to understand and influence it. [[Economic theory]] as a separate subject of its own came into being as the stresses of the new global order brought about two opposing theories of how a nation accumulates wealth: [[mercantilism|mercantilistic]] and [[free-trade]] policies. Mercantilism inflamed the growing hostilities between the increasingly centralized European powers as the accumulation of precious metals by governments was seen as important to the prestige and power of a modern nation. This involvement in accumulating gold and silver (among other things) became important in the development of the [[nation-state]]. Governments' involvement in trade affected the [[nobility]] of western European nations, because increased wealth by non-nobles threatened the nobility's place in society {{Citation needed|date=March 2025}}. ===Trade monopolies=== Governments became involved in trade directly through the granting of royal trade monopolies. For example, [[Walter Raleigh]] had been granted a trade monopoly by [[Elizabeth I of England|Queen Elizabeth]], for the export of [[broadcloth]] and wine.<ref name="isbn0-7656-0730-1">{{cite book |author=Markham, Jerry W. |title=A financial history of the United States |url=https://archive.org/details/financialhistory03mark_273 |url-access=limited |publisher=M.E. Sharpe |location=Armonk, N.Y. |year=2001 |page=[https://archive.org/details/financialhistory03mark_273/page/n34 22] |isbn=0-7656-0730-1 }}</ref> Ironically, competition between colonial powers led to their granting of trade monopolies to the [[East India Company|East India Companies]]. ===Triangular trade=== A [[triangular trade]] occurred in this period: between Africa, North and South America, and Europe; and it worked in the following way: Slaves came from Africa, and went to the Americas; raw materials came from the Americas and went to Europe; from there, finished goods came from Europe and were sold back to the Americas at a much higher price. Due the [[Population history of indigenous peoples of the Americas#Depopulation from disease|massive die-off]] of the indigenous people, the Americas had a local deficit of labor required for the extraction of resources (such as gold and silver) and farming. Europe was also recovering from the [[Black Plague]] and its resurgences, and population growth was slowed by intermittent warfare by European nations among themselves and against the Ottoman Empire. As a result of these limitations, the colonial powers were unable to satisfy the labor shortage through emigration, and the [[Atlantic Slave Trade]] was established to import the labor. This can be contrasted with the [[Qing dynasty]]'s colonization of [[Inner Asia]], whereby the high population in [[China proper]] produced policies that encouraged Han resettlement in [[Dzungaria]] during the 18th century, and [[Inner Mongolia]] and [[Manchuria]] during the 19th century.
Summary:
Please note that all contributions to Niidae Wiki may be edited, altered, or removed by other contributors. If you do not want your writing to be edited mercilessly, then do not submit it here.
You are also promising us that you wrote this yourself, or copied it from a public domain or similar free resource (see
Encyclopedia:Copyrights
for details).
Do not submit copyrighted work without permission!
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Search
Search
Editing
Commercial revolution
(section)
Add topic