Jump to content
Main menu
Main menu
move to sidebar
hide
Navigation
Main page
Recent changes
Random page
Help about MediaWiki
Special pages
Niidae Wiki
Search
Search
Appearance
Create account
Log in
Personal tools
Create account
Log in
Pages for logged out editors
learn more
Contributions
Talk
Editing
Nash equilibrium
(section)
Page
Discussion
English
Read
Edit
View history
Tools
Tools
move to sidebar
hide
Actions
Read
Edit
View history
General
What links here
Related changes
Page information
Appearance
move to sidebar
hide
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
=== Proof using the Kakutani fixed-point theorem === Nash's original proof (in his thesis) used Brouwer's fixed-point theorem (e.g., see below for a variant). This section presents a simpler proof via the [[Kakutani fixed-point theorem]], following Nash's 1950 paper (he credits [[David Gale]] with the observation that such a simplification is possible). To prove the existence of a Nash equilibrium, let <math>r_i(\sigma_{-i})</math> be the best response of player i to the strategies of all other players. <math display="block"> r_i(\sigma_{-i}) = \mathop{\underset{\sigma_i}{\operatorname{arg\,max}}} u_i (\sigma_i,\sigma_{-i}) </math> Here, <math>\sigma \in \Sigma</math>, where <math>\Sigma = \Sigma_i \times \Sigma_{-i}</math>, is a mixed-strategy profile in the set of all mixed strategies and <math> u_i </math> is the payoff function for player i. Define a [[set-valued function]] <math>r\colon \Sigma \rightarrow 2^\Sigma </math> such that <math>r = r_i(\sigma_{-i})\times r_{-i}(\sigma_{i}) </math>. The existence of a Nash equilibrium is equivalent to <math>r</math> having a fixed point. Kakutani's fixed point theorem guarantees the existence of a fixed point if the following four conditions are satisfied. # <math> \Sigma</math> is compact, convex, and nonempty. # <math>r(\sigma)</math> is nonempty. # <math>r(\sigma)</math> is [[Hemicontinuity|upper hemicontinuous]] # <math>r(\sigma)</math> is convex. Condition 1. is satisfied from the fact that <math>\Sigma</math> is a simplex and thus compact. Convexity follows from players' ability to mix strategies. <math>\Sigma</math> is nonempty as long as players have strategies. Condition 2. and 3. are satisfied by way of Berge's [[maximum theorem]]. Because <math> u_i </math> is continuous and compact, <math> r(\sigma_i) </math> is non-empty and [[Hemicontinuity|upper hemicontinuous]]. Condition 4. is satisfied as a result of mixed strategies. Suppose <math> \sigma_i, \sigma'_i \in r(\sigma_{-i}) </math>, then <math> \lambda \sigma_i + (1-\lambda) \sigma'_i \in r(\sigma_{-i}) </math>. i.e. if two strategies maximize payoffs, then a mix between the two strategies will yield the same payoff. Therefore, there exists a fixed point in <math> r </math> and a Nash equilibrium.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Fudenburg |first1=Drew |first2=Jean |last2=Tirole |title=Game Theory |publisher=MIT Press |year=1991 |isbn=978-0-262-06141-4 }}</ref> When Nash made this point to [[John von Neumann]] in 1949, von Neumann famously dismissed it with the words, "That's trivial, you know. That's just a [[fixed-point theorem]]." (See Nasar, 1998, p. 94.)
Summary:
Please note that all contributions to Niidae Wiki may be edited, altered, or removed by other contributors. If you do not want your writing to be edited mercilessly, then do not submit it here.
You are also promising us that you wrote this yourself, or copied it from a public domain or similar free resource (see
Encyclopedia:Copyrights
for details).
Do not submit copyrighted work without permission!
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Search
Search
Editing
Nash equilibrium
(section)
Add topic