Jump to content
Main menu
Main menu
move to sidebar
hide
Navigation
Main page
Recent changes
Random page
Help about MediaWiki
Special pages
Niidae Wiki
Search
Search
Appearance
Create account
Log in
Personal tools
Create account
Log in
Pages for logged out editors
learn more
Contributions
Talk
Editing
Auction
(section)
Page
Discussion
English
Read
Edit
View history
Tools
Tools
move to sidebar
hide
Actions
Read
Edit
View history
General
What links here
Related changes
Page information
Appearance
move to sidebar
hide
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
===Properties of auctioned goods=== [[File:The auction in Oulu 1962 (JOKAKAL3B-12356).tif|thumb|250px|The auction in [[Oulu|Oulu, Finland]], in September 1962. Auctioneer shows a table lamp with a final price of [[Finnish markka|FIM]] 6,100.]] [[Multiunit auction]]s sell more than one identical item at a time, rather than having separate auctions for each. This type can be further classified as either a [[uniform price auction]] or a [[discriminatory price auction]]. An example for them is [[spectrum auction]]s. A [[combinatorial auction]] is any auction for the simultaneous sale of more than one item where bidders can place bids on an "all-or-nothing" basis on "packages" rather than just individual items. That is, a bidder can specify that they will pay for items A and B, but only if they get ''both''.<ref name="combinatorial">{{Citation | last1 = Pekec | first1 = Aleksandar | last2 = Rothkopf | first2 = Michael H. | title = Combinatorial auction design | journal = Management Science | volume = 49 | issue = 11 | pages = 1485β1503 | date = November 2003 | doi = 10.1287/mnsc.49.11.1485.20585 | url = http://mansci.journal.informs.org/cgi/content/abstract/53/5/814 | issn = 1526-5501 | bibcode = 2003PNAS..10011153P | access-date = 2008-06-26 | archive-date = 2007-09-11 | archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20070911115539/http://mansci.journal.informs.org/cgi/content/abstract/53/5/814 }}</ref> In combinatorial auctions, determining the winning bidder(s) can be a complex process where even the bidder with the highest individual bid is not guaranteed to win.<ref name="combinatorial" /> For example, in an auction with four items (W, X, Y and Z), if Bidder A offers $50 for items W & Y, Bidder B offers $30 for items W & X, Bidder C offers $5 for items X & Z and Bidder D offers $30 for items Y & Z, the winners will be Bidders B & D while Bidder A misses out because the ''combined'' bids of Bidders B & D is higher ($60) than for Bidders A and C ($55). [[Deferred-acceptance auction]] is a special case of a combinatorial auction.<ref>{{cite CiteSeerX |last1=Milgromy|first1=Paul|last2=Segal|first2=Ilya|title=Deferred-Acceptance Auctions and RadioSpectrum Reallocation|date=September 11, 2014|citeseerx=10.1.1.715.9582}}</ref> Another special case of a combinatorial auction is the '''combinatorial clock auction''' (CCA), which combines a clock auction, during which bidders may provide their confirmations in response to the rising prices, with a subsequantial sealed bid auction, in which bidders submit sealed package bids. The auctioneer uses the final bids to compute the best value allocation and the Vickrey payments.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Bichler |first1=Martin |last2=Goeree |first2=Jacob K. |title=Handbook of Spectrum Auction Design |date=26 October 2017 |publisher=Cambridge University Press |isbn=978-1-107-13534-5 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=QA44DwAAQBAJ&pg=PA120 |access-date=22 October 2020 |language=en}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Ausubel |first1=Lawrence M. |last2=Baranov |first2=Oleg |title=A Practical Guide to the Combinatorial Clock Auction |journal=The Economic Journal |date=1 October 2017 |volume=127 |issue=605 |pages=F334βF350 |doi=10.1111/ecoj.12404 |s2cid=26571660 |url=https://academic.oup.com/ej/article-abstract/127/605/F334/5069450 |language=en |issn=0013-0133}}</ref> [[Generalized first-price auction]]s and [[Generalized second-price auction]]s offer slots for multiple bidders instead of making a single deal. The bidders get the slots according to the ranking of their bids. The second-price ruling is derived from the [[Vickrey auction]] and means the final deal sealing for the number one bidder is based on the second bidder's price.
Summary:
Please note that all contributions to Niidae Wiki may be edited, altered, or removed by other contributors. If you do not want your writing to be edited mercilessly, then do not submit it here.
You are also promising us that you wrote this yourself, or copied it from a public domain or similar free resource (see
Encyclopedia:Copyrights
for details).
Do not submit copyrighted work without permission!
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Search
Search
Editing
Auction
(section)
Add topic