Jump to content
Main menu
Main menu
move to sidebar
hide
Navigation
Main page
Recent changes
Random page
Help about MediaWiki
Special pages
Niidae Wiki
Search
Search
Appearance
Create account
Log in
Personal tools
Create account
Log in
Pages for logged out editors
learn more
Contributions
Talk
Editing
Financial economics
(section)
Page
Discussion
English
Read
Edit
View history
Tools
Tools
move to sidebar
hide
Actions
Read
Edit
View history
General
What links here
Related changes
Page information
Appearance
move to sidebar
hide
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
===Corporate finance theory=== {{see also|Outline of corporate finance #Theory}} [[Image:Manual decision tree.jpg|right|thumb|Project valuation via decision tree.]] Mirroring the [[#Certainty|above]] developments, corporate finance valuations and decisioning no longer need assume "certainty". [[Monte Carlo methods in finance]] allow financial analysts to construct "[[stochastic]]" or [[probabilistic]] corporate finance models, as opposed to the traditional static and [[deterministic]] models;<ref name="Damodaran_Risk"/> see {{section link|Corporate finance|Quantifying uncertainty}}. Relatedly, [[real options|Real Options theory]] allows for owner – i.e. managerial – actions that impact underlying value: by incorporating option pricing logic, these actions are then applied to a distribution of future outcomes, changing with time, which then determine the "project's" valuation today.<ref name="Damodaran"/> More traditionally, [[decision tree]]s – which are complementary – have been used to evaluate projects, by incorporating in the valuation (all) [[Event (probability theory)|possible events]] (or states) and consequent [[Decision making#Decision making in business and management|management decisions]];<ref>{{cite journal |title=Valuing Risky Projects: Option Pricing Theory and Decision Analysis |first1=James E. |last1=Smith |first2=Robert F. |last2=Nau |url=https://faculty.fuqua.duke.edu/~jes9/bio/Valuing_Risky_Projects.pdf |journal=Management Science |volume=41 |issue=5 |year=1995 |pages=795–816 |doi=10.1287/mnsc.41.5.795 |access-date=2017-08-17 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100612170613/http://faculty.fuqua.duke.edu/%7Ejes9/bio/Valuing_Risky_Projects.pdf |archive-date=2010-06-12 |url-status=live }}</ref><ref name="Damodaran_Risk">[[Aswath Damodaran]] (2007). [http://www.stern.nyu.edu/~adamodar/pdfiles/papers/probabilistic.pdf "Probabilistic Approaches: Scenario Analysis, Decision Trees and Simulations"]. In ''Strategic Risk Taking: A Framework for Risk Management''. Prentice Hall. {{ISBN|0137043775}}</ref> the correct discount rate here reflecting each decision-point's "non-diversifiable risk looking forward."<ref name="Damodaran_Risk"/> {{NoteTag| Simulation was first applied to (corporate) finance by [[David B. Hertz]] in 1964. Decision trees, a standard [[operations research]] tool, were applied to corporate finance also in the 1960s.<ref>See for example: {{cite journal |title= Decision Trees for Decision Making |first= John F. |url= https://hbr.org/1964/07/decision-trees-for-decision-making |last= Magee |journal= [[Harvard Business Review]] |volume= July 1964 |year= 1964 |pages= 795–816 |access-date= 2017-08-16 |archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20170816192517/https://hbr.org/1964/07/decision-trees-for-decision-making |archive-date= 2017-08-16 |url-status= live }}</ref> Real options in corporate finance were first discussed by [[Stewart Myers]] in 1977. }} Related to this, is the treatment of forecasted cashflows in [[equity valuation]]. In many cases, following Williams [[#Certainty|above]], the average (or most likely) cash-flows were discounted,<ref name="Markowitz_interview">{{cite journal |last= Kritzman |first= Mark |title= An Interview with Nobel Laureate Harry M. Markowitz |journal=Financial Analysts Journal |volume=73 |issue= 4|year= 2017|pages= 16–21|doi=10.2469/faj.v73.n4.3|s2cid= 158093964 }}</ref> as opposed to a theoretically correct state-by-state treatment under uncertainty; see comments under [[Financial modeling#Accounting|Financial modeling § Accounting]]. In more modern treatments, then, it is the ''expected'' cashflows (in the [[Expected value|mathematical sense]]: <math display=inline>\sum_{s}p_{s}X_{sj}</math>) combined into an overall value per forecast period which are discounted. <ref name="Kruschwitz and Löffler"/> <ref name="welch">[http://book.ivo-welch.info/read/chap13.pdf "Capital Budgeting Applications and Pitfalls"] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170815234404/http://book.ivo-welch.info/read/chap13.pdf |date=2017-08-15 }}. Ch 13 in [[Ivo Welch]] (2017). ''Corporate Finance'': 4th Edition</ref> <ref>George Chacko and Carolyn Evans (2014). ''Valuation: Methods and Models in Applied Corporate Finance''. FT Press. {{ISBN|0132905221}}</ref> <ref name="Damodaran_Risk"/> And using the CAPM – or extensions – the discounting here is at the risk-free rate plus a premium linked to the uncertainty of the entity or project cash flows <ref name="Damodaran_Risk"/> (essentially, <math>Y</math> and <math>r</math> combined). Other developments here include<ref>See Jensen and Smith under "External links", as well as Rubinstein under "Bibliography".</ref> [[agency theory]], which analyses the difficulties in motivating corporate management (the "agent"; in a different sense to the above) to act in the best interests of shareholders (the "principal"), rather than in their own interests; here emphasizing the issues interrelated with capital structure. <ref>{{cite journal|title=Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure|last1=Jensen|first1=Michael |last2=Meckling|first2=William|journal=Journal of Financial Economics |year=1976|volume=3|issue=4|pages=305–360|doi=10.1016/0304-405X(76)90026-X|doi-access=free}}</ref> [[Clean surplus accounting]] and the related [[residual income valuation]] provide a model that returns price as a function of earnings, expected returns, and change in [[book value]], as opposed to dividends. This approach, to some extent, arises due to the implicit contradiction of seeing value as a function of dividends, while also holding that dividend policy cannot influence value per Modigliani and Miller's "[[Irrelevance principle]]"; see {{section link|Dividend policy|Relevance of dividend policy}}. "Corporate finance" as a discipline more generally, building on Fisher [[#Certainty|above]], relates to the long term objective of maximizing the [[Enterprise value|value of the firm]] - and its [[Total shareholder return|return to shareholders]] - and thus also incorporates the areas of [[capital structure]] and [[dividend policy]]. <ref>[http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~adamodar/New_Home_Page/AppldCF/other/Image2.gif Corporate Finance: First Principles], from [[Aswath Damodaran]] (2022). ''Applied Corporate Finance: A User's Manual''. Wiley. {{ISBN|978-1118808931}}</ref> Extensions of the theory here then also consider these latter, as follows: (i) [[Corporate finance#Capitalization structure|optimization re capitalization structure]], and theories here as to corporate choices and behavior: [[Capital structure substitution theory]], [[Pecking order theory]], [[Market timing hypothesis]], [[Trade-off theory of capital structure|Trade-off theory]]; (ii) [[Corporate finance#Dividend policy|considerations and analysis re dividend policy]], additional to - and sometimes contrasting with - Modigliani-Miller, include: the [[Dividend policy#Walter's model|Walter model]], [[John Lintner#Lintner's dividend policy model|Lintner model]], [[Dividend policy#Residuals theory of dividends|Residuals theory]] and [[Dividend policy#Dividend signaling hypothesis|signaling hypothesis]], as well as discussion re the observed [[clientele effect]] and [[dividend puzzle]]. As described, the typical application of real options is to [[capital budgeting]] type problems. However, here, they are [[Corporate finance#Corporate governance|also applied]] to problems of capital structure and dividend policy, and to the related design of corporate securities; <ref name="Garbade">Kenneth D. Garbade (2001). ''Pricing Corporate Securities as Contingent Claims.'' [[MIT Press]]. {{ISBN|9780262072236}}</ref> and since stockholder and bondholders have different objective functions, in the analysis of the [[Corporate finance#Corporate governance|related agency problems]]. <ref name="Damodaran">{{cite journal|last=Damodaran|first=Aswath|author-link=Aswath Damodaran|title=The Promise and Peril of Real Options|journal=NYU Working Paper|issue=S-DRP-05-02|year=2005|url=http://stern.nyu.edu/~adamodar/pdfiles/papers/realopt.pdf|access-date=2016-12-14|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20010613082802/http://www.stern.nyu.edu/~adamodar/pdfiles/papers/realopt.pdf|archive-date=2001-06-13|url-status=live}}</ref> In all of these cases, state-prices can provide the market-implied information relating to the corporate, [[#State prices|as above]], which is then applied to the analysis. For example, [[convertible bond]]s can (must) be priced consistent with the (recovered) state-prices of the corporate's equity.<ref name="corp fin state prices"/><ref name="Kruschwitz and Löffler">See Kruschwitz and Löffler under Bibliography.</ref>
Summary:
Please note that all contributions to Niidae Wiki may be edited, altered, or removed by other contributors. If you do not want your writing to be edited mercilessly, then do not submit it here.
You are also promising us that you wrote this yourself, or copied it from a public domain or similar free resource (see
Encyclopedia:Copyrights
for details).
Do not submit copyrighted work without permission!
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Search
Search
Editing
Financial economics
(section)
Add topic