Jump to content
Main menu
Main menu
move to sidebar
hide
Navigation
Main page
Recent changes
Random page
Help about MediaWiki
Special pages
Niidae Wiki
Search
Search
Appearance
Create account
Log in
Personal tools
Create account
Log in
Pages for logged out editors
learn more
Contributions
Talk
Editing
Neoclassical economics
(section)
Page
Discussion
English
Read
Edit
View history
Tools
Tools
move to sidebar
hide
Actions
Read
Edit
View history
General
What links here
Related changes
Page information
Appearance
move to sidebar
hide
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
===Marginal revolution=== The change in economic theory from classical to neoclassical economics has been called the "[[Marginalism#The Marginal Revolution|marginal revolution]]", although it has been argued that the process was slower than the term suggests.<ref>[[Roger E. Backhouse]] (2008). "marginal revolution," ''[[The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics]]'', 2nd Edition. [http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_M000392&edition=current&q= Abstract] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160304233257/http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_M000392&edition=current&q= |date=March 4, 2016 }}.</ref> It is frequently dated from [[William Stanley Jevons]]'s ''Theory of Political Economy'' (1871), [[Carl Menger]]'s ''Principles of Economics'' (1871), and [[Léon Walras]]'s ''Elements of Pure Economics'' (1874–1877). Historians of economics and economists have debated: * Whether [[utility]] or marginalism was more essential to this revolution (whether the noun or the adjective in the phrase "marginal utility" is more important) * Whether there was a revolutionary change of thought or merely a gradual development and change of emphasis from their predecessors * Whether grouping these economists together disguises differences more important than their similarities.<ref name="William Jaffé 1976">William Jaffé (1976) "Menger, Jevons, and Walras De-Homogenized", ''Economic Inquiry'', V. 14 (December): 511–25</ref> In particular, Jevons saw his economics as an application and development of [[Jeremy Bentham]]'s utilitarianism and never had a fully developed [[general equilibrium theory]]. Menger did not embrace this hedonic conception, explained diminishing marginal utility in terms of subjective prioritization of possible uses, and emphasized disequilibrium and the discrete; further, Menger had an objection to the use of mathematics in economics, while the other two modeled their theories after 19th-century mechanics.<ref>Philip Mirowski (1989) ''More Heat than Light: Economics as Social Physics, Physics as Nature's Economics'', Cambridge University Press.</ref> Jevons built on the hedonic conception of Bentham or of Mill, while Walras was more interested in the interaction of markets than in explaining the individual psyche.<ref name="William Jaffé 1976"/> [[Alfred Marshall]]'s textbook, ''Principles of Economics'' (1890), was the dominant textbook in England a generation later. Marshall's influence extended elsewhere; Italians would compliment [[Maffeo Pantaleoni]] by calling him the "Marshall of Italy". Marshall thought [[classical economics]] attempted to explain prices by the [[cost of production theory of value|cost of production]]. He asserted that earlier marginalists went too far in correcting this imbalance by overemphasizing utility and demand. Marshall thought that "We might as reasonably dispute whether it is the upper or the under blade of a pair of scissors that cuts a piece of paper, as to whether the value is governed by utility or cost of production". Marshall explained price by the intersection of supply and demand curves. The introduction of different market "periods" was an important innovation of Marshall's: * Market period. The goods produced for sale on the market are taken as given data, e.g. in a fish market. Prices quickly adjust to clear markets. * Short period. Industrial capacity is taken as given. The level of output, the level of employment, the inputs of raw materials, and prices fluctuate to equate [[marginal cost]] and [[marginal revenue]], where profits are maximized. [[Economic rent]]s exist in short period equilibrium for fixed factors, and the rate of profit is not equated across sectors. * Long period. The stock of [[capital (economics)|capital]] goods, such as factories and machines, is not taken as given. Profit-maximizing equilibria determine both industrial capacity and the level at which it is operated. * Very long period. Technology, population trends, habits, and customs are not taken as given but allowed to vary in very long period models. Marshall took supply and demand as stable functions and extended supply and demand explanations of prices to all runs. He argued supply was easier to vary in longer runs, and thus became a more important determinant of price in the very long run.
Summary:
Please note that all contributions to Niidae Wiki may be edited, altered, or removed by other contributors. If you do not want your writing to be edited mercilessly, then do not submit it here.
You are also promising us that you wrote this yourself, or copied it from a public domain or similar free resource (see
Encyclopedia:Copyrights
for details).
Do not submit copyrighted work without permission!
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Search
Search
Editing
Neoclassical economics
(section)
Add topic