Jump to content
Main menu
Main menu
move to sidebar
hide
Navigation
Main page
Recent changes
Random page
Help about MediaWiki
Special pages
Niidae Wiki
Search
Search
Appearance
Create account
Log in
Personal tools
Create account
Log in
Pages for logged out editors
learn more
Contributions
Talk
Editing
Behavioral economics
(section)
Page
Discussion
English
Read
Edit
View history
Tools
Tools
move to sidebar
hide
Actions
Read
Edit
View history
General
What links here
Related changes
Page information
Appearance
move to sidebar
hide
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
=== Biases and fallacies === While heuristics are tactics or mental shortcuts to aid in the decision-making process, people are also affected by a number of [[biases]] and [[fallacies]]. Behavioral economics identifies a number of these biases that negatively affect decision making such as: '''Present bias''' [[Present bias]] reflects the human tendency to want rewards sooner. It describes people who are more likely to forego a greater payoff in the future in favour of receiving a smaller benefit sooner. An example of this is a smoker who is trying to quit. Although they know that in the future they will suffer health consequences, the immediate gain from the nicotine hit is more favourable to a person affected by present bias. Present bias is commonly split into people who are aware of their present bias (sophisticated) and those who are not (naive).<ref>O'Donoghue, Ted, and Matthew Rabin. 2015. "Present Bias: Lessons Learned and to Be Learned." American Economic Review, 105 (5): 273-79.</ref> '''Gambler's fallacy''' The [[gambler's fallacy]] stems from [[Hasty generalisation|law of small numbers]].<ref>{{cite book |last1=Cartwright |first1=Edward |title=Behavioral economics |date=2018 |publisher=Taylor & Francis Group |location=Abingdon, Oxon |isbn=9781138097117 |page=216 |edition=Third}}</ref> It is the belief that an event that has occurred often in the past is less likely to occur in the future, despite the probability remaining constant. For example, if a coin had been flipped three times and turned up heads every single time, a person influenced by the gambler's fallacy would predict that the next one ought to be tails because of the abnormal number of heads flipped in the past, even though the probability of a heads occurring is still 50%.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Croson |first1=Rachel |last2=Sundali |first2=James |date=2005-05-01 |title=The Gambler's Fallacy and the Hot Hand: Empirical Data from Casinos |url=https://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s11166-005-1153-2 |journal=Journal of Risk and Uncertainty |language=en |volume=30 |issue=3 |pages=195β209 |doi=10.1007/s11166-005-1153-2 |issn=1573-0476}}</ref> '''Hot hand fallacy''' The hot hand fallacy is the opposite of the gambler's fallacy. It is the belief that an event that has occurred often in the past is more likely to occur again in the future such that the streak will continue. This fallacy is particularly common within sports. For example, if a football team has consistently won the last few games they have participated in, then it is often said that they are 'on form' and thus, it is expected that the football team will maintain their winning streak.<ref name="Cartwright">{{cite book |last1=Cartwright |first1=Edward |title=Behavioral economics |date=2018 |location=Abingdon, Oxon |publisher=Routledge |isbn=9781138097117 |page=217 |edition=Third}}</ref> '''Narrative fallacy''' Narrative fallacy refers to when people use narratives to connect the dots between random events to make sense of arbitrary information. The term stems from Nassim Taleb's book ''[[The Black Swan: The Impact of the Highly Improbable]]''. The narrative fallacy can be problematic as it can lead to individuals making false cause-effect relationships between events.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Yesudian |first1=R. I. |last2=Yesudian |first2=P. D. |title=Case reports and narrative fallacies: the enigma of black swans in dermatology |journal=Clinical and Experimental Dermatology |date=27 November 2020 |volume=46 |issue=4 |pages=641β645 |doi=10.1111/ced.14504|pmid=33245798 |s2cid=227191908 }}</ref> For example, a startup may get funding because investors are swayed by a narrative that sounds plausible, rather than by a more reasoned analysis of available evidence.<ref>{{Cite web|title=Narrative Fallacy - Definition, Overview and Examples in Finance|url=https://corporatefinanceinstitute.com/resources/knowledge/trading-investing/narrative-fallacy/|access-date=2021-06-26|website=Corporate Finance Institute|language=en-US}}</ref> '''Loss aversion''' [[Loss aversion]] refers to the tendency to place greater weight on losses compared to equivalent gains. In other words, this means that when an individual receives a loss, this will cause their utility to decline more so than the same-sized gain.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Cartwright |first1=Edward |title=Behavioral economics |date=2018 |location=Abingdon, Oxon |publisher=Routledge |isbn=9781138097117 |page=47 |edition=Third}}</ref> This means that they are far more likely to try to assign a higher priority on avoiding losses than making investment gains. As a result, some investors might want a higher payout to compensate for losses. If the high payout is not likely, they might try to avoid losses altogether even if the investment's risk is acceptable from a rational standpoint.<ref>{{Cite web|last=Kenton|first=Will|title=Behavioral Finance Definition|url=https://www.investopedia.com/terms/b/behavioralfinance.asp|access-date=2020-09-21|website=Investopedia|language=en}}</ref> '''Recency bias''' [[Recency bias]] is the belief that a particular outcome is more probable simply because it had just occurred. For example, if the previous one or two flips were heads, a person affected by recency bias would continue to predict that heads would be flipped.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.imcusa.org/blogpost/334056/136102/721-Use-Cognitive-Biases-to-Your-Advantage#:~:text=Recency%20Bias%20%2D%20giving%20greater%20importance,made%20has%20a%20slight%20advantage)|title=''Use Cognitive Biases to Your Advantage'', Institute for Management Consultants, #721, December 19, 2011|access-date=November 1, 2020|archive-date=October 24, 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20201024151714/https://www.imcusa.org/blogpost/334056/136102/721-Use-Cognitive-Biases-to-Your-Advantage#:~:text=Recency%20Bias%20%2D%20giving%20greater%20importance,made%20has%20a%20slight%20advantage)|url-status=dead}}</ref> '''Confirmation bias''' [[Confirmation bias]] is the tendency to prefer information consistent with one's beliefs and discount evidence inconsistent with them.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Cartwright |first1=Edward |title=Behavioral economics |date=2018 |location=Abingdon, Oxon |publisher=Routledge |isbn=9781138097117 |page=213 |edition=Third}}</ref> '''Familiarity bias''' Familiarity bias simply describes the tendency of people to return to what they know and are comfortable with. Familiarity bias discourages affected people from exploring new options and may limit their ability to find an optimal solution.<ref>{{Cite web|title=10 cognitive biases that can lead to investment mistakes|url=http://www.magellangroup.com.au/insights/10-cognitive-biases-that-can-lead-to-investment-mistakes/|access-date=2020-09-21|website=Magellan Financial Group|language=en}}</ref> '''Status quo bias''' [[Status quo bias]] describes the tendency of people to keep things as they are. It is a particular aversion to change in favor of remaining comfortable with what is known.<ref>{{ Cite journal| last= Dean|first= M.|title=Limited attention and status quo bias. Journal of Economic Theory pp93-127|journal= Journal of Economic Theory|year= 2017|volume= 169|issue= C|pages= 93β127|doi= 10.1016/j.jet.2017.01.009|hdl= 10419/145423|url=https://econpapers.repec.org/article/eeejetheo/v_3a169_3ay_3a2017_3ai_3ac_3ap_3a93-127.htm|hdl-access= free}}</ref> Connected to this concept is the [[endowment effect]], a theory that people value things more if they own them - they require more to give up an object than they would be willing to pay to acquire it.<ref>{{cite web | url=https://thedecisionlab.com/reference-guide/economics/the-endowment-effect | title=The Endowment Effect }}</ref>
Summary:
Please note that all contributions to Niidae Wiki may be edited, altered, or removed by other contributors. If you do not want your writing to be edited mercilessly, then do not submit it here.
You are also promising us that you wrote this yourself, or copied it from a public domain or similar free resource (see
Encyclopedia:Copyrights
for details).
Do not submit copyrighted work without permission!
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Search
Search
Editing
Behavioral economics
(section)
Add topic