Jump to content
Main menu
Main menu
move to sidebar
hide
Navigation
Main page
Recent changes
Random page
Help about MediaWiki
Special pages
Niidae Wiki
Search
Search
Appearance
Create account
Log in
Personal tools
Create account
Log in
Pages for logged out editors
learn more
Contributions
Talk
Editing
Perfect competition
(section)
Page
Discussion
English
Read
Edit
View history
Tools
Tools
move to sidebar
hide
Actions
Read
Edit
View history
General
What links here
Related changes
Page information
Appearance
move to sidebar
hide
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
==Idealizing conditions of perfect competition== The definition of perfect competition is when the following conditions all hold:<ref>Bork, Robert H. (1993). The Antitrust Paradox (second edition). New York: Free Press. {{ISBN|0-02-904456-1}}.</ref> * '''A large number of sellers and buyers''' β A large number of consumers with the willingness and ability to buy the product at a certain price, and a large number of producers with the willingness and ability to supply the product at a certain price. As a result, individuals are unable to significantly influence prices.<ref>Gretsky, Neil E, Ostroy, Joseph M & Zame, William R, 1999. Perfect Competition in the Continuous Assignment Model. Journal of economic theory, 88(1), pp.60β118.</ref> One requirement for this is [[economies of scale|non-increasing returns to scale]] (including [[network effect]]s), ensuring that a monopoly doesn't push out competitors. * '''[[Product (business)|Homogeneous products]]''': The products are perfect substitutes for each other (i.e., the qualities and characteristics of a market good or service do not vary between different suppliers). * '''Utility maximizing participants''': [[Homo economicus|Rational buyers]] always attempt to maximize their [[economic utility]] and sellers attempt to maximize their profit. * '''[[Perfect information]]''': All consumers and producers know all prices of products and utilities they would get from owning each product.<ref name="Robinson, J. 1934"/> * '''Zero [[transaction cost]]s''': Buyers and sellers do not incur costs in making an exchange of goods. This includes no barriers to [[Barriers to entry|entry]] or [[Barriers to exit|exit]] (no [[sunk costs]]) and perfect [[factor mobility]] where the [[factors of production]] are perfectly mobile and costlessly, allowing workers to freely move between firms and other adjustments to changing market conditions.<ref name="Robinson, J. 1934">Robinson, J. (1934). What is perfect competition?. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 49(1), 104-120.</ref> * '''No [[externalities]]''': Costs or benefits of an activity do not affect third parties. This criterion also excludes any [[government intervention]]. * '''Well defined [[Property rights (economics)|property rights]]''': These determine what may be sold, as well as what rights are conferred on the buyer. While no real market is perfect, many markets are considered to be near enough to perfect for predictions from economic theory to be reasonably accurate. It has been proven that if the above conditions hold, that every participant will be a [[price taker]] and will not have [[Market power|market power to set prices]], and all sellers will operate such that their [[marginal costs]] equal their [[marginal revenue]]. There are many instances in which there exist "similar" products that are [[Substitute good|close substitutes]] (such as butter and margarine), which are [[Marginal rate of substitution|relatively easily interchangeable]], so that a rise in the price of one good will cause a significant shift to the consumption of the close substitute. If the cost of changing a firm's manufacturing process to produce the substitute is also relatively "[[Materiality_(auditing)|immaterial]]" in relationship to the firm's overall profit and cost, this is sufficient to ensure that an economic situation isn't significantly different from a perfectly competitive economic [[Market (economics)|market]].<ref>Roger LeRoy Miller, "Intermediate Microeconomics Theory Issues Applications, Third Edition", New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc, 1982. <br> Edwin Mansfield, "Micro-Economics Theory and Applications, 3rd Edition", New York and London:W.W. Norton and Company, 1979. <br> Henderson, James M., and Richard E. Quandt, "Micro Economic Theory, A Mathematical Approach. 3rd Edition", New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1980. Glenview, Illinois: Scott, Foresmand and Company, 1988. <br> John Black, "Oxford Dictionary of Economics", New York: Oxford University Press, 2003. <br> Tirole, Jean, "The Theory of Industrial Organization", Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press, 1988.</ref>
Summary:
Please note that all contributions to Niidae Wiki may be edited, altered, or removed by other contributors. If you do not want your writing to be edited mercilessly, then do not submit it here.
You are also promising us that you wrote this yourself, or copied it from a public domain or similar free resource (see
Encyclopedia:Copyrights
for details).
Do not submit copyrighted work without permission!
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Search
Search
Editing
Perfect competition
(section)
Add topic